The 1980s Takeover Era and Lipton’s Stockholder Rights Plan

Short-Termism and the Takeover Era

The principles espoused in Takeover Bids formed the foundation for the takeover battles of the 1980s, and the most important defensive innovation in that era, the stockholder rights plan (colloquially known as the “poison pill”), which was invented by Lipton with colleagues at Wachtell Lipton.  The need for the stockholder rights plan and other takeover defenses was inspired by Lipton’s belief that the takeover practices of financial raiders during this period had become abusive and needed to be curbed.  But, despite the fame of the poison pill and other defensive tactics, Lipton was not against all takeover activity:

I believe in the free market.  I believe that there should be a free market in corporate control.  I do not think that all mergers should be banned.  I do not think that bigness is bad.  I do not think that our economic and political systems are threatened by concentration of corporate power through takeovers.  I do think that very serious corporate takeover abuses have developed in recent years.61

The debate surrounding increasingly widespread use of the pill in takeover defenses of the 1980s inspired this illustration from the Legal Times in 1983.

These takeover abuses arose out of the financialization of takeover activity, as the more traditional friendly strategic merger, which were in fact themselves rare before the 1990s, were replaced by hostile takeovers foisted on target companies involuntarily.  These takeovers often involved financial buyers, who used “bootstrap” debt financing to acquire companies, using the target companies’ assets as the security, to pay themselves out lucrative immediate returns, and either dismantling the target companies through sales or leaving them with so much debt that they had to cut their future investment plans, and cut jobs and close plants and other facilities.  As Lipton observed, “[s]ignificant changes [had] occurred in the takeover environment in recent months.  Prior to 1981 the billion-dollar hostile tender offer was hard to imagine.  Now multi-billion dollar bids can readily be financed.  Prior to 1981 most bids were any and all cash offers; now the two-tier, front-end loaded offer is the most popular (and the most powerful).”62  The ready availability of multi-billion dollar financing meant that, for the first time, “the size of a company cannot, in and of itself, be considered a defense against a takeover.”63

Lipton warned in Congressional testimony in 1985 that supporting financialized takeovers was “a policy that favors the present at the expense of the future.”  But, as Lipton observed, “[u]nfortunately, the future has no political constituency”64:

The situation can be analogized to a farmer who does not rotate his crops, does not periodically let his land lie fallow, does not fertilize his land and does not protect his land by building fences, planting cover, and creating windbreaks.  In the early years our farmer will maximize his return from the land.  It is a very profitable short-term use.  But inevitably it leads to a dust bowl and economic disaster.65

Lipton warned of the dangers of short-termism and saw irony in the failure of government to regulate takeovers despite those dangers:

Long-term planning by business corporations is essential to the future health of our economy, yet in the one area of corporate takeovers, we suffer the strange anomaly of the Government through the SEC arguing that all that counts is immediate profits to shareholders, that corporations should be subject to bootstrap raids through front-end loaded tender offers, and that corporate directors who seek to do long-term planning and serve the long-term interests of all corporate constituencies should not be protected by the business judgment rule.66

The results of those policies were companies that were highly leveraged and myopic in focus, “which comes at the expense of employees, customers, suppliers, communities in which the companies operate and in the long run the nation’s economy as a whole.”67

Long-term planning by business corporations is essential to the future health of our economy.

Beyond their negative economic effects on the specific target companies and their stakeholders, allowing hostile takeovers motivated by financial engineering, not long-term business considerations, also had a larger systemic effect in Lipton’s view.  As Lipton warned in Takeover Bids, if corporate boards faced the constant possibility of being forced to sell, it disrupted their ability to invest and implement business plans focusing on sustainable, socially responsible growth.68  As Lipton observed five years later in 1984, hostile acquisitions “preempt[ed] the ability of the target’s board of directors to determine the desirability, price, form, and timing of a merger of the company, a matter which every state corporation law commits to the hands of the company’s board of directors.”69

By the end of the decade, crafty evolutions of the pill were required to fend off increasingly sophisticated attacks.

In view of these dangers, Lipton advocated throughout the 1980s for legislation, building on the U.K. Takeover Code, to reform what he viewed as abusive takeover tactics.70  But, recognizing the unlikelihood of congressional legislation, Lipton worked to develop a defensive arsenal for boards of directors to deploy themselves to protect their companies.  The most powerful form of defensive self-help was to become the stockholder rights plan, later also known more commonly as the “poison pill.”

Origins of the Rights Plan

The stockholder rights plan is the single most important tool developed to make real Lipton’s philosophy that the elected board of a company should control the company’s destiny even when facing a takeover bid.  Where Takeover Bids set forth the principles underlying Lipton’s conclusion that boards should remain active decision-makers in the face of a takeover, the stockholder rights plan provided an effective instrument for them to do so.

Although the stockholder rights plan had previously been discussed in internal memoranda, Lipton first put the rights plan on display in a memo to clients dated June 20, 1983.71  Lipton began by reaffirming the values espoused in Takeover Bids in no uncertain terms:

We believe that a corporation has the absolute right to

  1. have a policy of remaining an independent entity,
  2. have a policy of refusing to entertain takeover proposals,
  3. reject a takeover bid,
  4. take action to remain an independent entity, and
  5. guarantee its shareholders a right to retain an equity interest in the corporation even if someone is successful in obtaining control and forcing a second-step merger.72

Lipton then identified the core problem:  The financialization of takeover activity had created a fundamental disconnect between the corporation’s right to remain independent and resist takeover bids, and its practical ability to do so when faced with the coercive power of a hostile tender offer.  Lipton noted that it had “become virtually impossible to defend against the stampeding effect of partial and front-end loaded tender offers and assure all shareholders of fair treatment,” and that the SEC “has not recommended new rules which would redress the imbalance” between independent companies and hostile acquirors.73  Lipton noted that litigation, charter amendments, legislation, counter tender offers, and capitalization changes had been successful to some degree, but that “none of these means has proven to be generally applicable and effective.”74  Lipton also recognized that defensive measures like self-tenders that required companies to leverage up and cut future investment were unsatisfying because they compromised company focus on sustainable growth in similar ways to the bids they were developed to defeat.  What was needed was a defense that would do no harm to the company’s value and allow it to proceed with its long-term strategy to create value.

Lipton presented the rights plan as a solution to these problems, and as a way of defending against a bid while doing no harm to the company’s business strategy and balance sheet.  From the outset, however, he was clear that the rights plan “does not prevent tender offers and does not prevent a second-step merger after a raider has seized control.  All it does is assure fair treatment of all shareholders and the right of those who so desire to continue their equity interest following a takeover.”75  In other words, the right plan fit with Lipton’s belief that the threat to be addressed was not takeovers themselves, but takeover abuses.

“The Plan is simple.”76  Though its effects were powerful, its mechanics were straightforward, reflecting an innovative application of existing corporate finance techniques.  The first iteration of the Plan, known as a “flip-over” plan, would distribute a dividend of convertible preferred stock (and later, of purchase rights) to all common stockholders, convertible into “the same (or larger) number of shares of common as are outstanding.”  The rights were issued when the bidder, having obtained control of the target, took steps to cash out the remaining stockholders or to otherwise engage in another merger, and would dilute the acquirer substantially in comparison to the other stockholders.  Lipton counted the “flip-over” provision as among the “normal boilerplate provisions protecting the conversion rights in the event of a merger or other business combination.”77  When such a merger occurred, “the conversion rights would flip-over to the common stock of the raider and the preferred would be convertible into the common stock of the raider.”78  The dilutive flip-over provision formed the “essence of the Plan” by presenting “a difficult problem to a raider contemplating a hostile tender offer.  A raider must think twice about the economics of being faced with the issuance of a significant number of shares of its own common stock.”79  The reason is simple: the flip-over when triggered would seriously dilute the acquirer, and thus strip it of much or all of the value it thought it was purchasing. 

The Plan is simple.

Importantly, the original pill did not include a so-called “flip-in” trigger.  A flip-in prevented a bidder who wished to acquire a company from exceeding a certain toe-hold (later to be commonly set between 10% and 20%) of the target’s shares without triggering the rights to be issued to other common stockholders, and massive dilution of the bidder.  A flip-in, if upheld in court, prevented an acquisition of control in the first instance and blocked even a so-called “creeping” acquisition that might be the first step in a control change.  Initially, Lipton was dubious about the validity of a flip-in and did not include it in his first rights plans, a decision that was to be useful later when the validity of the pill faced its most important initial test in the Delaware Supreme Court.80

Sample of a client memo regarding “Poison Pills”.

Recognizing that other defensive tactics had amounted to half-measures at most, Lipton placed great weight on this solution and staked his and Wachtell Lipton’s reputation on its validity, stating that “[w]e have no doubts about the legality of the plan.  More important, we are convinced of its efficacy in achieving the objectives referred to above.”81  Two months later, Lipton further emphasized the general applicability of the pill, encouraging companies to consider “implementing the Plan before a takeover situation arises,”82 and providing a “suggested model form” for the plan.83  Lipton also noted that the Plan had been used by three companies trading on the NYSE — Bell & Howell, ENSTAR, and Lenox.  Those three pioneer plans had been adopted under “special circumstances,” but Lipton began advocating for companies to adopt plans under ordinary circumstances, before any takeover attempt had begun, foreseeing that business-judgment arguments would be more persuasive if the adoption of the rights plan had been made by the board on a clear day.84

Although Lipton had expressed confidence in the legality of the rights plan, as an innovation, he understood it would be the subject of rigorous testing in court.  For example, Bell & Howell’s plan was challenged in the Delaware Court of Chancery in 1983, but the court refused to enjoin (on 48 hours’ notice) the issuance of preferred stock under the plan, noting that it was impossible to sufficiently consider the parties’ arguments, and that the merits would need to be considered at a later time, after the issuance, while recognizing that at that point “it may be difficult to fashion an appropriate remedy.”85  The validity of Bell & Howell’s pill was not further litigated.  Having noted that the court’s decision would be “a major factor in determining whether to implement the Plan,”86 the court’s refusal to enjoin the pill paved the way for further adoptions of rights plans.

In February 1985, The Economist helped readers understand takeover defense tactics, describing T. Boone Pickens’s and Carl Icahn’s separate attempts on Phillips Petroleum.

It was in the context of the Lenox takeover fight that the rights plan achieved its notorious nickname, with the Wall Street Journal noting in June 1983 that the strategy being used in Lenox’s takeover battle “is being referred to on Wall Street as ‘the poison-pill defense.’”87  Lipton would later lament the name as “a most unfortunate misnomer.  It is neither a pill nor poisonous.  It is merely a compact between a company and its shareholders designed to protect against takeover abuses and assure the shareholders of a fair price and fair treatment.”88  Nevertheless, perhaps owing to the evocative language and its increasingly common usage, Lipton frequently embraced the usage of the “poison pill” name, including in the titles of his own memos.89

The validity of Lenox’s and ENSTAR’s pills were likewise never decided on the merits, although in considering Lenox’s pill, the Court of Chancery noted that “the ‘poison pill’ amendments measure, enacted by the Board when ‘takeover’ fever gripped the industry, could be considered legitimate exercises of Board discretion designed to protect the stockholders against a less than arms-length sale.”90  That early reference to the pill as a matter of board discretion would form the precursor to the most important case upholding the validity of the pill, Moran v. Household International, Inc.,91 discussed in the next section.

Takeover Defense Comes To Delaware:  UnocalMoranRevlon

It was not until 1985 that Lipton’s position on takeover defense and tactics, and the rights plan (or poison pill) of his creation, were directly addressed by the Delaware courts.  Then, in the space of nine months, the Delaware Supreme Court issued three opinions that per force took the measure of Lipton’s views, and have long remained the cornerstone of Delaware’s takeover jurisprudence.

Unocal.92  On June 10, 1985, in Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d 946 (Del. 1985), the Delaware Supreme Court for the first time considered the proper role of directors of a corporation faced with an unsolicited takeover bid and the nature of judicial review to be employed when that director’s conduct is challenged as a breach of fiduciary duty.  The decision came in the context of what the Court called “an issue of first impression in Delaware — the validity of a corporation’s self-tender for its own shares which excludes from participation a stockholder making a hostile tender offer for the company’s stock.”93  Reversing the Court of Chancery, the Court stated:

The factual findings of the Vice Chancellor, fully supported by the record, establish that Unocal’s board, consisting of a majority of independent directors, acted in good faith, and after reasonable investigation found that Mesa’s tender offer was both inadequate and coercive.  Under the circumstances the board had both the power and duty to oppose a bid it perceived to be harmful to the corporate enterprise.  On this record we are satisfied that the device Unocal adopted is reasonable in relation to the threat posed, and that the board acted in the proper exercise of sound business judgment.  We will not substitute our views for those of the board if the latter’s decision can be “attributed to any rational business purpose.”94

Raider T. Boone Pickens, CEO of Mesa Petroleum, made a bid for Unocal in 1985. The Delaware Supreme Court’s decision on the matter helped cement the legal rationale behind the pill.

The Court’s analysis relied in significant respects on Lipton’s Takeover Bids article and other related writings.  Addressing first “the basic issue of the power of a board of directors of a Delaware corporation to adopt a defensive measure of this type,” the Court echoed Lipton’s argument that such power derived from the directors’ power to manage the corporation’s “business and affairs” under DGCL § 141(a), as well as the board’s “fundamental duty and obligation to protect the corporate enterprise, which includes stockholders, from harm reasonably perceived, irrespective of its source.”95  Pointedly rejecting the position of Lipton’s antagonists, the Court declared that “in the broad context of corporate governance, including issues of fundamental corporate change, a board of directors is not a passive instrumentality.”96  And, specifically in this regard, the Court repeated one of Lipton’s key points that under the corporate statute, director action is a “prerequisite to the ultimate disposition of such matters” as mergers, charter amendments, sales of assets and dissolution.97

Turning to the question of judicial review, the Court referenced the “intense debate among practicing members of the bar,” citing to Lipton’s Takeover Bids and the contrary writings of Easterbrook and Fischel.98  As a first principle, the Court held that in responding to a takeover bid, “a board’s duty is no different from any other responsibility it shoulders, and its decisions should be no less entitled to the respect they otherwise would be accorded in the realm of business judgment.”99  That said, the Court identified “an enhanced duty” of “judicial examination at the threshold” owing to the “omnipresent specter that a board may be acting primarily in its own interests.”100  That “inherent conflict,” the Court held, required directors to show that “reasonable grounds for believing that a danger to corporate policy and effectiveness,” and that any defensive measure be “reasonable in relation to the threat posed.”101  Thus, the Court embraced Lipton’s basic views but with an important distinction.  It innovated a new intermediate standard of review that was more intensive than the business judgment rule’s bare rationality standard, and that required a showing of reasonable care and loyalty, and a reasonable fit between the threat the corporation faced and the means selected to defend it.  But that standard was a manageable one for boards to meet if they used the approach Lipton recommended in Takeover Bids, and was meaningfully less intrusive than “entire fairness” review.

In elaborating on that new intermediate standard of review, the Court noted the important role of independent directors on the target board, a topic Lipton had long highlighted, and indicated that when a majority of independent directors decided to take defensive action, that gave enhanced credibility to the board’s ability to meet its burden of reasonableness under the new test the decision articulated.102  Notably, the Unocal board used techniques Lipton had outlined in Takeover Bids, such as separate meetings of the independent directors, extensive presentations by independent advisors, and truly deliberative meetings, the failure of which had been a principal focus of the Delaware Supreme Court’s decision earlier in the year in Smith v. Van Gorkom, 488 A.2d 858 (Del. 1985).  The use of these techniques led to the Supreme Court crediting the Unocal board’s good faith and diligence.

The Court also relied directly on Lipton’s stakeholder position and views on the coerciveness of partial two-tier tender offers, citing again to Takeover Bids and a related paper based on it:

This entails an analysis by the directors of the nature of the takeover bid and its effect on the corporate enterprise.  Examples of such concerns may include:  inadequacy of the price offered, nature and timing of the offer, questions of illegality, the impact on “constituencies” other than shareholders (i.e., creditors, customers, employees, and perhaps even the community generally), the risk of nonconsummation, and the quality of securities being offered in the exchange.  See Lipton and Brownstein, Takeover Responses and Directors’ Responsibilities:  An Update, p. 7, ABA National Institute on the Dynamics of Corporate Control (December 8, 1983).  While not a controlling factor, it also seems to us that a board may reasonably consider the basic stockholder interests at stake, including those of short term speculators, whose actions may have fueled the coercive aspect of the offer at the expense of the long term investor.11  Here, the threat posed was viewed by the Unocal board as a grossly inadequate two-tier coercive tender offer coupled with the threat of greenmail.

11There has been much debate respecting such stockholder interests.  One rather impressive study indicates that the stock of over 50 percent of target companies, who resisted hostile takeovers, later traded at higher market prices than the rejected offer price, or were acquired after the tender offer was defeated by another company at a price higher than the offer price.  [Citing Takeover Bids.] Moreover, an update by Kidder Peabody & Company of this study, involving the stock prices of target companies that have defeated hostile tender offers during the period from 1973 to 1982 demonstrates that in a majority of cases the target’s shareholders benefited from the defeat.  The stock of 81% of the targets studied has, since the tender offer, sold at prices higher than the tender offer price.  When adjusted for the time value of money, the figure is 64%.  See Lipton & Brownstein, supra ABA Institute at 10.  The thesis being that this strongly supports application of the business judgment rule in response to takeover threats.  There is, however, a rather vehement contrary view.  See Easterbrook & Fischel, supra 36 Bus. Law. at 1739-45.

Specifically, the Unocal directors had concluded that the value of Unocal was substantially above the $54 per share offered in cash at the front end.  Furthermore, they determined that the subordinated securities to be exchanged in Mesa’s announced squeeze out of the remaining shareholders in the “back-end” merger were “junk bonds” worth far less than $54.  It is now well recognized that such offers are a classic coercive measure designed to stampede shareholders into tendering at the first tier, even if the price is inadequate, out of fear of what they will receive at the back end of the transaction.103

The leading corporate law judge of the era, Chancellor Allen, depicted with the member of the Supreme Court most interested in corporate law in that era, Justice Andrew G.T. Moore, II, in a photo that illustrates the sometimes tense relationship between Chancery and the Supreme Court in this high-stakes era.

At the same time as the decision in Unocal vindicated Lipton’s basic view of the law of takeover defense, it also highlighted a frustration that was largely resolved by his development of the pill.  Although the Unocal board prevailed, the tactics it used in many ways mirrored that of the hostile bidder itself (Pickens’ Mesa Petroleum) because Unocal stockholders were presented by management with a coercive, partial self-tender offer into which they had to tender or risk being left on the back end of a more levered company in which debt holders with a high coupon rate had high priority, and a company that was less well positioned to investment in new ventures.  Thus, on both a doctrinal and practical level, Lipton’s twin views that boards had the legal authority to defend, but could use a tool that would be less harmful to the target corporations and their stakeholders, were advanced by the doctrinal and practical outcome of Unocal.

Moran.104  Serendipitously, the validity of Lipton’s Rights Plan came before the Delaware Supreme Court while the Unocal case was under submission.  The pill case, Moran v. Household International, Inc., 500 A.2d 1346 (Del. 1985), was submitted in the Supreme Court on May 21, 1985 — five days after Unocal was submitted — and decided on November 19, 1985, some five months after the Unocal decision. 

This high-stakes drama was unusual in a couple of respects.  First, the challenge to the pill was not in the context of a pending bid, but rather in the form of what was essentially an action for a declaratory judgment that Lipton’s creation was invalid in all conceivable circumstances.  A director of Household, who was also the chairman of Household’s largest single stockholder (Dyson-Kissner-Moran Corporation) that reportedly had some interest in possibly making a future offer, was Skadden’s client.  No bid was pending.  The pill that had been adopted was the first generation “flip-over” pill, that entitled the Household stockholders, in the event of a merger with the Rights not having been redeemed by the board of directors, to purchase $200 of the common stock of the tender offeror for $100.  Notably, the Rights in the Household pill provided for the stockholders to receive a non-trivial payment for redemption ($.50 per Right) — a feature that would change in later pills so that the price of redemption was essentially costless to the company.  Most importantly, the pill had no flip-in feature.  Thus, a bidder could acquire control and live with a minority, if it was willing to forego a merger or other consolidation. 

Second, Lipton’s longtime friend and the leading lawyer for hostile bidders, Joe Flom and his Skadden firm had helped inspire the litigation, and put a full team into the battle to have the pill declared invalid under Delaware corporate law.  Lipton fielded an “A Team” of his own at Wachtell Lipton, led by his fellow founding partner, George A. Katz.

Wachtell Lipton founder George Katz played a leading role in helping Lipton in key takeover battles, and as a close friend and colleague. It was not by coincidence that when the pill’s validity was at issue in Moran, Katz was chosen to lead the Wachtell Lipton team.

Reflecting the high stakes, the trial involved prominent expert witnesses from business and academia testifying about the practical and legal consequences of the pill.  For example, to defend the pill, the Wachtell Lipton litigation team put on Jay Higgins, head of the M&A department at Solomon Bros., and Raymond Troubh, a former partner of Lazard Freres with extensive firsthand experience in merger and acquisition deals.  To advance its position that the pill was a show-stopper that would improperly interfere with the rights of stockholders under Delaware law, and with their rights under the Williams Act to accept tender offers, Skadden put on Harvard Business School Professor Michael Jensen and University of Michigan Business School Professor Michael Bradley, along with Alan Greenberg, then CEO of Bear Stearns and considered by many to be the dean of arbitrageur practice.  The context of the case was helpful to Lipton and his team.  Given the prevalence of coercive, two-tiered tender offers and the need of the trial court to consider all the possible circumstances in which the pill could be used, the Skadden team found it more difficult to prove its case because without director action, there was no way to prevent coercion of stockholders by these offers, which were permissible under federal law.  Not only that, because there was no pending bid and because Skadden was attacking the validity of the pill in general and not its use in a particular situation, Skadden bore the difficult burden of showing that the pill could not be lawfully used in any circumstance.

In holding for the Household board and refusing to strike down their adoption of the pill, the Court of Chancery pointed to the bidder practices then prevalent, finding that the board had ample basis for considering Household vulnerable to a “two-tier” takeover via that coercive practice in which stockholders were forced to tender lest they be “frozen out” of any premium once the bidder acquired control.  The Court of Chancery also rejected Skadden’s arguments that the pill was impermissible because it treated the bidder, as a stockholder, differently from other stockholders, and the Rights were “sham” securities impermissible under the Delaware corporation statute.105

When the decision in Unocal came down, that boded ill for the appeal of that decision.  In Unocal, it had been argued that exempting Pickens from the company’s own offer was improperly discriminatory, but the Delaware Supreme Court rejected that argument, citing with some irony to past cases permitting greenmail payments to raiders like Pickens.  Thus, the reality that once the flip-over rights were triggered, the rights plan would dilute the acquirer by granting a large amount of equity to all the other stockholders was rendered of little utility to the opponents of the pill. 

Unocal presaged the outcome in the Moran appeal in an even clearer way.  In Unocal, it had been argued that the board’s defense twisted powers given to them under the Delaware General Corporation Law beyond their intended purpose.  The Supreme Court rejected that argument in Unocal, stating:  “[O]ur corporate law is not static.  It must grow and develop in response to, indeed in anticipation of, evolving concepts and needs.”106  That elemental idea well served the defenders of the pill, who argued for the acceptance of a clearly innovative interpretation of Delaware law in response to the then-prevalent, coercive tactic of the “two-tier” tender offer.

In Moran, one of the principal arguments against the poison pill was that the provisions of Delaware law that authorized boards to issue rights to stockholders was designed to permit the issuance to stockholders of rights to purchase shares of their own corporation and for financing purposes, not to give them “rights” that were only designed to thwart their ability to receive a tender offer.  The Supreme Court rejected this argument, noting that the rights issued were authorized by the plain language of the statute, and quoting its recent Unocal decision, that statutes should not be confined in their application, but be applied in accord with their language to address evolving business circumstances.107  In its analysis, the Court thus held that board power to adopt a Rights Plan existed under the Delaware General Corporation Law, including by accepting that the plan was “analogous to ‘anti-destruction’ or ‘anti-dilution’ provisions which are customary features of a wide variety of corporate securities” — the very origin for the idea of the pill that Lipton has often pointed to.108

Moran also applied the new Unocal intermediate standard of review in considering whether Household’s adoption of the pills was, as Chancery had found, a “legitimate exercise of business judgment.”109  In affirming that finding, the Court’s opinion noted Lipton’s role in advising the Household board:

The minutes reflect that Mr. Lipton explained to the Board that his recommendation of the Plan was based on his understanding that the Board was concerned about the increasing frequency of “bust-up” takeovers, the increasing takeover activity in the financial service industry, such as Leucadia’s attempt to take over Arco, and the possible adverse effect this type of activity could have on employees and others concerned with and vital to the continuing successful operation of Household even in the absence of any actual bust-up takeover attempt.  Against this factual background, the Plan was approved.110

Responding to the challenge that the Rights Plan “usurped stockholders’ rights to receive trade offers,” the Court — again accepting key parts of Lipton’s pill advocacy — concluded “that the Rights Plan does not prevent stockholders from receiving tender offers” and “that the change of Household’s structure was less than that which results from the implementation of other defensive mechanisms upheld by various courts.”  Serendipity again helped Lipton and his pill defenders.  In a high-profile situation, Sir James Goldsmith had acquired control of Crown Zellerbach, which also had a flip-over pill.  Thus, the Supreme Court found that the flip-over pill was not a “show stopper” but could be gotten “around” by that and other methods by which Household could still be acquired by a hostile bidder (the Court listed tender offers conditioned on redemption of the Rights, tenders with high minimums, soliciting consents or running a proxy contest to remove the board and redeem the pill).111 

The odd procedural context also led to another important feature of the Moran decision.  In addition to citing the stockholders’ ability to elect a new board that could lift the pill as a way around it, the Court made clear that neither its ruling that the pill was not invalid in all circumstances nor that the pill’s initial  adoption by the Household board was proper, gave the Household board a blank check to use that pill indefinitely  against a specific future bid.  Rather, when that happened the new Unocal standard would be applied to the directors’ decision to whether to redeem (or “pull”) the pill in the heat of an actual bid with specific terms: 

When the Household Board of Directors is faced with a tender offer and a request to redeem the Rights, they will not be able to arbitrarily reject the offer.  They will be held to the same fiduciary standards any other board of directors would be held to in deciding to adopt a defensive mechanism, the same standard as they were held to in originally approving the Rights Plan.  See Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954–55, 958.

The Rights Plan will result in no more of a structural change than any other defensive mechanism adopted by a board of directors.  The Rights Plan does not destroy the assets of the corporation.  The implementation of the Plan neither results in any outflow of money from the corporation nor impairs its financial flexibility.  It does not dilute earnings per share and does not have any adverse tax consequences for the corporation or its stockholders.  The Plan has not adversely affected the market price of Household’s stock.

Comparing the Rights Plan with other defensive mechanisms, it does less harm to the value structure of the corporation than do the other mechanisms. . . . .

There is little change in the governance structure as a result of the adoption of the Rights Plan.  The Board does not now have unfettered discretion in refusing to redeem the Rights.  The Board has no more discretion in refusing to redeem the Rights than it does in enacting any defensive mechanism. . . . .

We conclude that there was sufficient evidence at trial to support the Vice-Chancellor’s finding that the effect upon proxy contests will be minimal.  Evidence at trial established that many proxy contests are won with an insurgent ownership of less than 20%, and that very large holdings are no guarantee of success.  There was also testimony that the key variable in proxy contest success in the merit of an insurgent’s issues, not the size of his holdings. . . . .

The Directors adopted the Plan in the good faith belief that it was necessary to protect Household from coercive acquisition techniques.  The Board was informed as to the details of the Plan.  In addition, Household has demonstrated that the Plan is reasonable in relation to the threat posed.  Appellants, on the other hand, have failed to convince us that the Directors breached any fiduciary duty in their adoption of the Rights Plan.

While we conclude for present purposes that the Household Directors are protected by the business judgment rule, that does not end the matter.  The ultimate response to an actual takeover bid must be judged by the Directors’ actions at that time, and nothing we say here relieves them of their basic fundamental duties to the corporation and its stockholders.  [Citations omitted.]  Their use of the Plan will be evaluated when and if the issue arises.112

Delaware’s validation of the Rights Plan as a legitimate defensive mechanism was, like Unocal, an emphatic validation of the approach to takeovers advocated by Lipton.  Two days after the Supreme Court’s decision, Lipton reaffirmed that “[a] Rights Plan is legal.  A Rights Plan is within the business judgment of the board of directors.”113  Once again, he reminded clients that a “Rights Plan should be adopted before a company becomes a target.”114

At the same time, Lipton attacked the Wall Street Journal’s anti-Moran editorial (“Et Tu, Delaware”),115 and noting that “takeover entrepreneurs and speculators hate Rights Plans and are continuing their campaign to outlaw them”:

While Rights Plans do not prevent all take overs, they do protect against abusive takeover tactics and they do deter bust-up, bootstrap, two-tier, junk bond takeovers.  Naturally those who profit from these takeovers at the expense of American business, workers and communities, and whose wildly speculative activities threaten our entire economic system, oppose anything that restricts their activities.  There is no stronger argument for implementing a Rights Plan now.116

Revlon.117  The third of the 1985-86 trilogy in Delaware turned primarily not on a takeover defense in isolation, but a “lock-up option” agreed to by a target board of directors to secure a higher-priced LBO takeover bid to block an initial hostile suitor.  In Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (Del. 1986), the Delaware Supreme Court affirmed an injunction against a “crown jewel” lock-up option granted by the Revlon board to Forstmann Little & Co., the financial sponsor of an LBO, as part of the company’s response to the unsolicited efforts of a Ronald Perelman company (Pantry Pride, Inc.) to acquire Revlon.  

[I]t would be very helpful if statutes permitting directors to consider constituencies other than shareholders were adopted in Delaware and the other states.

Previously, in response to Perelman’s hostile bid, the Revlon board had approved — on Lipton’s advice — a Note Purchase Rights Plan under which Revlon stockholders received as a dividend one Note Purchase Right to acquire a $65 principal Revlon one-year note at 12% interest in exchange for one common share, triggered by anyone acquiring 20% or more of Revlon’s shares unless that person acquired all shares at $65 cash per share or more; as in a pill, the Rights were not available to the acquiror and could be redeemed by the board prior to a 20% triggering event.  In addition, Revlon had responded to Perelman’s $47.50 per share offer with a self-tender for up to 10 million shares, in exchange for $47.50 principal Notes and preferred stock — which was fully accepted by the Revlon stockholders.  After further bidding by Perelman, the Revlon board agreed to a $56 per share cash deal with Forstmann, with management participating in the new company, and Forstmann assuming Revlon’s debt incurred by the issuance of the Notes; as part of the deal, Revlon would redeem the Rights.  After Perelman raised to $56.25/share conditioned on the board’s removal of the Rights (and announced that he would top any Forstmann offer by a slightly higher one), Forstmann countered with a $57.25 per share offer, conditioned on receiving a lock-up option to acquire Revlon’s vision and health divisions for $525 million — which was $100.175 million below value; management would not participate, and Forstmann committed to support the par value of the Notes, which had fallen in the market, by an exchange of new notes.  The Revlon board agreed to the option, because the Forstmann bid was higher than Perelman’s and it protected the Noteholders (who had only just recently been solely stockholders of Revlon and had received the Notes in exchange for some of their Revlon shares as part of a defensive self-tender).  In response, Perelman raised to $58/share conditioned on nullification of the Rights and an injunction against the Forstmann lock-up.

The New York Times: Tiny Delaware’s Corporate Clout June 1, 1986

In its opinion, the Supreme Court framed the issue before it as requiring decision “for the first time the extent to which a corporation may consider the impact of a takeover threat on constituencies other than shareholders,” citing Unocal.118  The Court approved the Revlon board’s adoption of the Note Purchase Rights Plan as “protect[ing] the shareholders from a hostile takeover at a price below the company’s intrinsic value [at that point, Perelman’s $45 bid], while retaining sufficient flexibility to address any proposal deemed to be in the stockholders’ best interests.”119  The Court, however, held that the “usefulness” of the Rights had become moot once the Revlon board agreed to their redemption in favor of the Forstmann white-knight transaction, thereby “moot[ing] any question of their propriety under Moran or Unocal.”120  The Court also approved Revlon’s defensive self-tender in which its board encouraged stockholders to exchange some of their shares of Revlon for the Notes.  Nonetheless, the Court held that the Revlon board’s responsibilities changed once it authorized the negotiation of the sale of the company to Forstmann:

The Revlon board’s authorization permitting management to negotiate a merger or buyout with a third party was a recognition that the company was for sale.  The duty of the board had thus changed from the preservation of Revlon as a corporate entity to the maximization of the company’s value at a sale for the stockholders’ benefit.  This significantly altered the board’s responsibilities under the Unocal standards.  It no longer faced threats to corporate policy and effectiveness, or to the stockholders’ interests, from a grossly inadequate bid.  The whole question of defensive measures became moot.  The directors’ role changed from defenders of the corporate bastion to auctioneers charged with getting the best price for the stockholders at a sale of the company.121

Going further, the Court rejected the Revlon board’s position that it was entitled to protect the Noteholders — as only the Forstmann bid then did — under the constituency concept of the Unocal opinion:

Such a focus was inconsistent with the changed concept of the directors’ responsibilities at this stage of the developments.  The impending waiver of the Notes covenants had caused the value of the Notes to fall, and the board was aware of the noteholders’ ire as well as their subsequent threats of suit.  The directors thus made support of the Notes an integral part of the company’s dealings with Forstmann, even though their primary responsibility at this stage was to the equity owners.

The original threat posed by Pantry Pride — the break-up of the company — had become a reality which even the directors embraced.  Selective dealing to fend off a hostile but determined bidder was no longer a proper objective.  Instead, obtaining the highest price for the benefit of the stockholders should have been the central theme guiding director action.  Thus, the Revlon board could not make the requisite showing of good faith by preferring the noteholders and ignoring its duty of loyalty to the shareholders.  The rights of the former already were fixed by contract.  [Citations omitted.]  The noteholders required no further protection, and when the Revlon board entered into an auction-ending lock-up agreement with Forstmann on the basis of impermissible considerations at the expense of the shareholders, the directors breached their primary duty of loyalty.The Revlon board argued that it acted in good faith in protecting the noteholders because Unocal permits consideration of other corporate constituencies.  Although such considerations may be permissible, there are fundamental limitations upon that prerogative.  A board may have regard for various constituencies in discharging its responsibilities, provided there are rationally related benefits accruing to the stockholders.  Unocal, 493 A.2d at 955.  However, such concern for non-stockholder interests is inappropriate when an auction among active bidders is in progress, and the object no longer is to protect or maintain the corporate enterprise but to sell it to the highest bidder.122

The Supreme Court’s decision that the Noteholders’ interests could not be considered was important and striking.  Not only was it directly in conflict with its statement in Unocal, the ruling addressed Noteholders who were also likely still Revlon stockholders and had received their Notes for some of their shares just weeks before at the urging of the Revlon board and with the promise that the independent directors would protect their value.  Thus, the best deal for them would depend on the combined value of what they received for their stock and their Notes.  Put simply, no group of stakeholders could be closer to being stockholders than the Revlon Noteholders.  But, when Revlon’s lawyer on appeal raised this argument at the beginning of his presentation, citing to Unocal, the Justice who authored Unocal cut him off and said that Unocal had not meant what it said in its dictum about other constituencies.123  In its decision, the Supreme Court seemed most disturbed by Revlon’s refusal to put Perelman on a level playing field with Forstmann and it is impossible to determine whether if it had given Perelman a chance to bid on equal terms so long as he provided comparable note protection, how the case and contest itself might have come out.  But, as a matter of reality and doctrine, Revlon resulted in a holding that sharply limited the ability of boards to protect stakeholders once they had decided to sell the company. 

Revlon thus opened the door to eschewing the Lipton-style consideration of corporate constituencies that some had thought to be a centerpiece of Unocal — at least once the target board itself had decided to sell the company, and thereby moved from “defenders of the corporate bastion to auctioneers charged with getting the best price for the stockholders at a sale of the company.”124  The nature of that new role, and the question of what triggers it, became the centerpiece of continued debate and litigation in the years, and decades, that followed, and that is still central in the current debates over corporate purpose.  

Even though the Revlon opinion did not pull back on the propriety of takeover defenses (and indeed approved the Revlon board’s initial, aggressive defensive tactics), Lipton viewed the opinion as creating “confusion” and as seeming “to retreat somewhat” from Unocal; he urged that “it would be very helpful if statutes permitting directors to consider constituencies other than shareholders were adopted in Delaware and the other states.”125  Lipton then fueled that movement, in which a majority of American states, but not Delaware, adopted statutes that rejected Revlon and allowed boards to consider all stakeholders when addressing takeovers and M&A more generally.126

As to the injunction against the Forstmann lock-up option, Lipton concluded that “it is difficult to draw clear guidelines” about lock-ups, and that although Revlon said that “not all lockups are illegal,” “the trend in the courts is unfavorable.”127  A few years later, Lipton was quoted as labeling the Revlon decision “a horrendous mistake” that was “dead wrong to second-guess a competent board of directors.”128  But, coming out of Revlon, the most immediate challenge to the cause of takeover defense championed by Lipton was how the nascent Unocal standard would be applied in cases before the Court of Chancery, especially as bidders were beginning to present all-shares, all-cash bids that could not readily be characterized as structurally coercive.  Unocal itself signaled more deference to boards than Revlon did, and Moran’s admonition that boards’ use of pills would be reviewed in light of the specific bid presented set the stage for another period in which Lipton’s perspective on takeovers would be tested in the market and court.

The Validity of Flip-In Pills Is Tested and Established

In June 1986, Lipton wrote that “the poison pill has been adopted by about 200 major corporations and has proved to be effective.”129  By October, “[w]ell over 300 companies have adopted rights plans.”130  And in his memo commemorating the first anniversary of Household, Lipton noted that 29% of Fortune 500 companies and 36% of Fortune 200 companies had adopted rights plans.131  By July 1987, the rights plan had been adopted by over 400 companies.132  And by November 1988, that figure had grown to more than 800.133

By the end of the decade, crafty evolutions of the pill were required to fend off increasingly sophisticated attacks.

Although Lipton had staked his own reputation on the validity of the flip-over rights plan, he continued to strike a cautious tone as to its more aggressive sibling — a pill that combined a flip-over provision as in Lipton’s original pill with a more assertive flip-in provision.  Flip-in provisions “give the shareholders the right to buy additional shares at a bargain price whenever a raider crosses a threshold that varies from plan to plan.”134  Because of the substantial dilution that would be imposed upon the raider that crosses the plan’s threshold, Lipton saw a flip-in as “a major deterrent to open-market accumulations, partial tender offers and tenders where the raider would purchase 50% or more and not undertake a second-step merger and thereby avoid triggering the basic flip-over provision.”135  Lipton acknowledged that “including a flip-in provision would, of course, strengthen our rights plan,” but refrained from doing so “out of fear that a court would find that it was illegal and that it tainted the validity of the whole rights plan.” 136

In Europe and other regions of the world, acquirers would obtain control of public companies and not merge out the remaining stockholders.  American takeover bidders began to adapt to this approach in the face of the flip-over pill.  For that reason, many companies and other law firms began adopting versions of the pill with a flip-in feature that would be triggered by any acquisition of shares above a certain percentage, such as 15 percent, and could thus block a change in control from happening at all.  Lipton was aware of these developments, but was conservative in moving toward the flip-in pill.  While remaining focused on curbing not takeovers, but takeover abuses, Lipton began to endorse some measured provisions that had flip-in aspects but would be triggered only in the case of potential abuse and not simply because a bidder crossed a certain ownership threshold without board approval (i.e., a “status flip-in”):

The Rights Plan also provides protection against self-dealing transactions by a 20% shareholder.  If a 20% shareholder were to effect an acquisition of the issuing company by means of a reverse merger in which the company and its stock survive, or engage in certain self-dealing transactions with the issuing company (such as sales of assets to the company or obtaining certain financial benefits from the company), each right not owned by such shareholder would become exercisable for that number of shares of the issuing company’s common stock which at the time of such transaction would have a market value of two times the exercise price of the right.  Thus, although an acquiror may acquire a controlling block without effecting a second step, he will be penalized if he uses his control position to treat the issuing company’s shareholders unfairly.137

Consistent with his focus on abuses not blocking all changes of control, Lipton reiterated that this self-dealing-triggered flip-in provision “does not prevent takeovers” and “has no effect on an acquiror who is willing to acquire control and not obtain 100% ownership through a merger until after the rights have expired provided that the acquiror does not engage in self-dealing transactions with the issuing company.”138

Lipton’s early caution regarding flip-in provisions turned out to be warranted.  As the judicial waters were tested, courts distinguished flip-in provisions from flip-over provisions, finding in certain instances that flip-in provisions were invalid.  Even flip-in-provisions triggered only by self-dealing, such as the one endorsed by Lipton, were invalidated in the NL Industries case, in which the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York found the flip-in provision invalid under New Jersey law:

[T]he rights plan, and in particular the flip-in provision of that plan . . . is ultra vires as a matter of New Jersey Business Corporation law.  The flip-in effects a discrimination among shareholders of the same class or series.  Under the plan the voting rights and the equity of an acquiring shareholder are diluted upon a triggering event. . . . New Jersey law clearly does not allow discrimination among shareholders of the same class and series.139

The court expressly distinguished Household on the ground that Household contained “only a flip-over,” and because the Court in Household found that the rights plan in question did not impede the tender offer process, while the court found that the plan in NL Industries “does prevent stockholders from receiving tender offers.”140

Having endorsed the validity of flip-in provisions triggered only upon instances of self-dealing, Lipton responded to the NL decision in no uncertain terms:

[W]e believe that the NL decision is wrong.  We believe it is an erroneous interpretation of New Jersey corporate law and an erroneous view of the effect of Rights Plans. . . . We continue to believe that Rights Plans of the Household type (flip-over) and NL type (flip-over and flip-in for protection against self-dealing) are valid and legal and are highly desirable in this era of coercive, bust-up, junk-bond, boot-strap takeovers.141

Despite NL Industries, Lipton remained optimistic regarding stockholder rights plans generally, writing that occasional adverse rulings “will not stop the movement” toward rights plans.  “At most, they will eliminate the flip-in provisions contained in some plans and bring home the message that the best time to adopt a plan is before an attack.”142  Lipton viewed the challenges to rights plans as “demonstrat[ing] that Rights Plans in fact are a very effective counter to today’s coercive takeover techniques”143 that “have proved to be very effective in curbing abusive takeover tactics and increasing the negotiating strength of the target’s board.”144  Confident that judicial momentum would continue trending toward Delaware’s rulings, Lipton wrote:  “We continue to believe that the decisions of the Delaware Supreme [C]ourt in the Household and Revlon cases are the correct view as to Rights Plans and we continue to recommend the adoption of Rights Plans.”145

The U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit’s 1986 opinion in CTS,146 authored by Judge, and former Chicago Law School Professor, Richard Posner, marked a milestone in the endorsement of the validity of the flip-in rights plan.  Lipton viewed the decision as having “great significance, particularly in light of Judge Posner’s express distaste for poison pills.”147  Judge Posner’s background in law and economics deriving from his important and prominent work148 while at the University of Chicago (alongside takeover defense opponents Frank Easterbrook (later a Judge of the 7th Circuit himself) and Dan Fischel) made the victory for the rights plan especially satisfying for Lipton.  Stemming back to the intellectual debate over Takeover Bids, Lipton had long observed that the stock market-oriented Chicago school was antithetical to takeover defenses.  To Lipton, Chicago school economists, “[w]ith their efficient market theories, they point to stock markets’ favorable reactions to takeovers as proof that takeovers are good for the economy,”149 while the deleterious effects of takeovers “are well-nigh invisible to those economists of the Chicago school (and their special friends among law professors) who are in love with takeovers.”150  Thus, as Lipton wrote, “[t]he Pill is an anathema to the Chicago School,”151 making Judge Posner’s decision to uphold the district court’s refusal to enjoin the rights plan all the more important.  Lipton considered the opinion “an extremely important reaffirmation of the basic legality of poison pills established by the Supreme Court of Delaware” and hoped that it would be “instructive to other federal courts which have taken a more restrictive view.”152  That said, it should be noted that Judge Posner’s view of rights plans remained lukewarm at best.  As the opinion notes, CTS’s first attempt at creating a rights plan that could withstand enhanced scrutiny under Unocal “clearly flunked the test,” and in upholding its second rights plan, Judge Posner expressed his continued “skepticism concerning the propriety of poison pills.”153

Though a less noteworthy decision, the federal district court decision in Gelco Corp. v. Coniston Partners likewise allowed Lipton to applaud the court’s validation of “both a flip-over and a 20% flip-in” as “a correct statement of the law with respect to poison pills,” noting that the court “specifically rejected the questionable reading of New Jersey law in the NL case.”154  Thus, a year after Household and after a number of subsequent court victories, Lipton’s assessment of the judicial landscape was optimistic, even with respect to flip-in provisions:

On balance, it appears that most courts will follow Household and today there is relatively little doubt as to legality, even with respect to the flip-in provision that has caused the most difficulty in the courts.155

Institutional Investors and the Rights Plan

Outside the courtroom, the most significant debate over the rights plan occurred between Lipton and institutional investors, which had risen to power and become key participants in the 1980s takeover era.  Lipton’s engagement with the rising influence of institutional investors was initiated in his Takeover Bids article, and would continue, to this date, to be a principal focus of his concerns over whether the American corporate governance system is appropriately oriented toward sustainable wealth creation and the fair treatment of employees and other company stakeholders.

In the 1980s, Lipton viewed institutional investors as responsible for much of the focus on short-term financial results that had fueled the financialization of takeovers.  Lipton viewed the nation as having entered the “the age of finance corporatism, which is dominated by the institutional investor and the professional investment manager.  The existence of large pools of capital managed to maximize short-term performance has fueled a wave of highly leveraged takeovers that threatens a variety of constituencies, including shareholders, employees, customers, suppliers, and communities, as well as the economy as a whole.”156  Of institutional investors, Lipton observed:  “Never in the history of our modern economic development has so much economic power been held by so few.”157  

Never in the history of our modern economic development has so much economic power been held by so few.

Institutional investors’ focus on short-term financial results at the expense of society was antithetical to Lipton’s beliefs, arising from his studies under Adolph Berle, in the “enterprise theory — the concept that corporations should be managed not just in the interests of the shareholders, but in the interests of the enterprise as a whole, which includes, of course, the employees, customers, suppliers, and the community in which a corporation lives.”158  As Lipton observed, “the shareholders-only view ignores the reality that other constituencies both share the risk and are vital to the success of corporate activity.”159  Lipton wrote that “management historically pursued socially beneficial objectives such as expanding the enterprise, improving productivity, and cultivating planning, research, and development.  In contrast, the new control persons — the institutional investors — share none of these social goals.”160  As to institutional investors’ support for takeovers, Lipton did not mince words in sounding the alarm, writing that institutional investors “are using their power to force corporations to focus on short-term profits rather than long-term growth” and “forcing massive reductions in research and development and capital investment.”161  As a result, “institutional investors are not just insisting on a takeover premium when a company is put in play, they are actively promoting takeovers.”162  He regarded institutional investors as agents that “have gained control of virtually every major company” and “show no restraint and no regard for the public good,” and cautioned that they “must be policed. . . .  We must mandate that they be long-term investors not short-term speculators and promoters of takeovers.”163

[T]he shareholders-only view ignores the reality that other constituencies both share the risk and are vital to the success of corporate activity.

As to the deteriorating relationship between management and institutional investors, Lipton’s view was bleak:

Despite their protestations against the charge that they sell out good management that has good long-term prospects, institutional investors continue to do so and continue to discourage the long-term investments that are essential for American business to remain competitive in the world market.164

Lipton described the susceptibility of management to takeovers resulting from the pressures imposed by institutional investors:

American management has lost confidence in institutional investors.  Management views institutional investors as effectively controlling the price of securities through their market activity with no regard for the long term needs of corporations and their managements.  Long term profitability may require measures that will reduce earnings in the short term, but institutional investors are too concerned with quarter-to-quarter performance of their managed assets . . . This depresses the value of a farsighted company’s securities and makes the company an attractive takeover target.  Thus, management may be forced to choose between prudent management and avoiding a takeover battle.165

Underlying the short-term pressures imposed by institutional investors lay an important question — why were these investors so susceptible to the temptations of short-termism and takeovers?  Quoting Warren Buffett, Lipton noted the irony that institutional investors, “which should have the longest investment perspective, have been transformed by the competitive race on Wall Street into some of the most speculative players around.”166  As Lipton noted, “competitive pressures also drove many of the fiduciaries that hold most of the country’s private capital, including pension funds, into the [takeover] game.”167  

Lipton observed that these competitive pressures were driven by the short-term pressures placed on fund managers, whose interests were not necessarily aligned with the institutional investor, much less the companies in which they were invested:

Institutional investors also exacerbate the situation by preferring short-term gains to long-term growth.  Institutions will accept any premium over the current stock market price rather than hold a portfolio investment for appreciation.  Competitive necessity mandates this investment policy:  To survive, institutional investment managers must perform better than the market as a whole.  Their profession forces investment managers to not only accept usual takeover premiums but also to join ranks with takeover entrepreneurs to pressure companies into new deals that will produce a premium over the current market.  Takeover entrepreneurs have gained the active support of major institutional investors.168

Despite his pessimistic appraisal of the short-term philosophy of institutional investors, Lipton recognized that, if their incentive problems could be corrected, the rising prominence of institutional investors could present “a unique opportunity to bridge the corporate governance gap between ownership and control”:

Most corporations now have shareholders who are sufficiently large to have a real stake in corporate governance and sufficiently professional to possess the skills necessary to bring their influence to bear.  As such, shareholder democracy, which heretofore has been viewed as inherently unworkable because small, diversified shareholders generally lack the interest to become involved in corporate governance, can become a reality.  

Self-interest motivates institutional investors to actively seek — including by promoting or encouraging hostile takeovers — short-term investment profits.  The full benefits of shareholder democracy cannot be achieved until the short-term focus of investment managers and the competitive pressures they face are rectified.169

If these fund managers’ incentive problems could be cured, Lipton saw institutional investors as potentially being recalibrated “to provide ‘patient’ capital to permit management to make the long-term investments that are essential for a strong economy.  We must develop long-term relationships between companies and their institutional investors, with the investors being committed to support management’s long-term business plans.”170  Doing so would allow institutional investors to support long-term economic growth:

Institutions will best serve their beneficiaries by shifting their focus from short-term trading strategies to policies that encourage corporations to seek long-term growth.  This is the only way in which all investors and citizens benefit.

As the total assets under control of institutional investors become larger, their returns must tend towards the market averages by default if not by design.  Their future is tied less to a selective portfolio and more to the general economic health of the country.  From the standpoint of the market as a whole, stock investing is a zero sum game.  Institutions will best serve their beneficiaries by shifting their focus from short-term trading strategies to policies that encourage corporations to seek long-term growth.  This is the only way in which all investors and citizens benefit.171

Lipton advocated for solving the institutional incentives problem by encouraging long-term investment through “a tax on institutional investors which takes away all profit on stock held less than one year and most of the profit on stock held less than five years.”172  But although he noted that “the need for legislation is clear,” Lipton recognized that congressional action and tax policy change was not likely, and therefore reiterated that “it is essential that the poison pill — which is the only effective brake on the takeover frenzy — be sustained.”173  It is against this backdrop that institutional investors mounted their campaigns against the rights plan.

The Anti-Pill Campaign

Having largely failed in the courts, the opponents of the rights plan sought to “destroy its effectiveness by proposing sponsoring restrictive SEC rules and presenting proxy statement proposals to subject the Pill to a form of shareholder referendum.”174  Institutional investors were leaders in those attacks.  Lipton observed that “institutional investors are joining with corporate raiders to attempt to eliminate defenses against takeover abuses.”175  The aforementioned incentive problems were acutely displayed when institutional investors attacked the stockholder rights plan:

In evaluating these attacks, the self-interest of the managers of these institutions should be noted.  They are not investors.  They are speculators.  They are compensated on the basis of how much quick profit they produce each quarter.  They do not invest.  They buy and sell.  They do not have any long-term interest in the companies whose securities they trade in.  . . . They are self-interested promoters of takeovers for their own benefit.  They are fueling the takeover frenzy.  They encourage raiders, buy billions of dollars of junk bonds to finance bust-up takeovers and act in concert to defeat efforts to protect against takeover abuses.176

Lipton provided companies with a model response to requests to include a shareholder referendum on rights plans at the annual meeting.  That model response featured much of Lipton’s cautionary language concerning takeover activities, noting that “bidders have engaged in abusive tactics” and have “little or no regard for the interests of the stockholders of the target company. . . .  Our Rights Plan helps to level the playing field between the Company and such bidders.”177  In keeping with his message that rights plans allow for negotiation of superior offers, and do not prevent takeovers outright, Lipton wrote that the rights plan will “allow the board to perform its traditional role of responding to, and negotiating with, a prospective acquiror on behalf of the Company and its diverse body of stockholders.”178  Lipton’s model response reminded stockholders that “[t]he Rights Plan does not prevent the making of an acquisition proposal or the acceptance of an acquisition proposal that the Board finds to be in the interests of stockholders.”179  And in all events, “[i]n determining whether to redeem our Rights Plan in the context of a specific proposal, your Board has an obligation to meet its fiduciary duties and exercise its business judgment.”180  

As Lipton observed:  “One manifestation of increased activism on the part of institutional investors has been the formation of institutional investor organizations to oppose takeover defenses.”181  One such manifestation was the Council of Institutional Investors, which led a widespread anti-rights plan campaign, supported by the California Public Employees Retirement System and the College Retirement Equity Fund.  Of the Council of Institutional Investors, Lipton observed that it “was formed for the stated purpose of getting involved in corporate governance,” yet its endeavors resulted in causing companies to enter into leveraged recapitalizations and focused on attacking defenses against abusive takeover tactics, including the poison pill, and to oppose takeover reform.  “In other words, in the guise of a program to improve corporate governance the Council and its members are attempting to determine the outcome of takeover battles and to exercise control over the major American business corporations.”182

In January 1985, the New York Times Magazine ran this article on the “national scandal” of junk-bond takeovers, quoting Marty Lipton.

In 1987, Lipton was invited by Penn ILE Director Professor Michael Wachter and Dean Robert Mundheim to give one of the ILE’s first lectures, which became the basis for an important article published by the Penn Law Review.

This proxy campaign played out in both 1987 and 1988 annual meeting seasons.  Lipton followed the campaign closely and updated clients on the “score” as it unfolded, as the referendum was an important indicator of whether the poison pill had reached acceptance not only by the courts, but by stockholders.  Lipton warned:

By their campaign against the poison pill, [College Retirement Equity Fund] and the California Retirement System are demonstrating that their self-interest comes before the public interest.  If a large number of institutional investors join in this campaign, it will be clear that we cannot rely on self-restraint in the exercise of their power over American corporations and that corrective legislation is the only solution.183

Institutional investors’ resolutions to abolish rights plans were largely voted down in 1987, marking a victory for the rights plan in the court of public opinion.  Stockholders of International Paper Co. rejected an anti-right plan resolution, with less than 20% of shares voting in favor, which Lipton noted was a demonstration of “what can be accomplished when corporate management takes the opportunity to present its case to the shareholders.”184  That was the first of many victories for the rights plan in the 1987 proxy season.  In the end, Lipton counted a total of 31 companies targeted with anti-rights plan campaigns — not one was successful.  As Lipton thus reported, “the Council of Institutional Investors has suffered a stunning defeat in its proxy campaign against the poison pill.”185   

In the 1988 annual meeting season, institutional investors returned with another campaign against the rights plan.  Lipton predicted that the second generation pill’s inclusion of a stockholder vote (as discussed below) would “enable the large number of pension fund managers who do recognize the dangers of the junk-bond, bust-up takeover frenzy, to vote against the anti-pill resolution.”186  Thus, Lipton began to bolster the second generation rights plan against the next proxy season and against the institutional investors who had “become activists in opposing takeover defenses, voting for corporate raiders in proxy fights and forcing companies to auction themselves to the high bidder.”187  Once again, the institutional investors’ campaigns failed at the ballot box, a result that Lipton attributed to “shareholders recogniz[ing] that the pill is an important protection against abusive takeover tactics.”188  Thus, despite what Lipton characterized as an “intensified anti-pill campaign by CREF, Calpers and their cohorts,”189 a study of the 1988 proxy season found that “voting statistics do not reveal a trend of growing shareholder support for these proposals.”190  Lipton celebrated this result, noting that “despite great effort and special targeting this year, the opponents of Rights Plans failed to achieve greater support this year than they did last year.”191

As time would tell, however, these initial institutional investor attempts to reduce the prevalence of poison pills were but the first wave of such efforts in coming decades.

In the Wake of CTS, Lipton Embraces the Flip-In and Recommends It to Clients 

With the rights plan having proved successful both in the courts and at annual meetings, Lipton wrote a memo in July 1987 that introduced a new and more powerful “second-generation” rights plan.  Lipton surveyed the effects of and challenges to pills over the previous years, noting that it “has proved to be the most effective protection against abusive takeover tactics,” “has been upheld by most courts that have considered it,” and “has been adopted by over 400 companies.”192  At the same time, Lipton noted that the takeover frenzy had continued, with a litany of takeover abuses from the corporate raider’s “extensive arsenal of powerful takeover weapons,” including, among other abuses, the raider’s ability to “ignore moral obligations to employees, customers, suppliers and communities and bust up a target,” and to “take over a target through a creeping or partial tender offer and then take advantage of the public minority shareholders through self-dealing and conflict transactions,” to “mobilize institutional shareholders to attack any attempt by a target to defeat a takeover and remain an independent company,” and to “usurp the traditional functions of a board of directors to act and negotiate on behalf of the shareholders in a merger.”193  In other words, despite the initial success of the first-generation rights plan, takeover proponents continued to threaten both the enterprise theory of the corporation and the model of board-centric determinism Lipton endorsed in Takeover Bids.  

Recognizing both the success of the original pill and the continued effectiveness of the weapons of hostile acquirors, Lipton proposed that “this is clearly an appropriate time to reexamine the pill.”  In his second-generation rights plan, Lipton finally advocated for “a flip-in at the 20% acquisition threshold,”194 whether or not there was a threat of self-dealing.  That provision would thereby “give[] shareholders of the target, other than the raider, the right to cause unacceptable dilution of the raider’s holdings in the target.”195  It would prevent raiders from acquiring a controlling position through open market purchases, regardless of their subsequent intentions, and would protect shareholders from the possibility that a raider would “avoid[] the effect of the flip-over by not doing a second-step merger after acquiring control.”196

Cognizant of the potential for judicial skepticism over such a potent flip-in provision, and in order to maintain a balance between preventing takeover abuses and allowing shareholders to consider acquisition proposals, Lipton tempered the new proposal by “providing for a shareholder vote if a non-abusive takeover is proposed.”197  The second-generation pill would include a new provision:

[I]f a bidder (who does not hold more than 1% of the shares of the company and therefore is not a greenmailer or a free rider seeking to profit by putting the company in play) proposes to acquire all of the shares of the company for cash at a fair price and has financing or financing commitments, then the company will, if requested by the bidder, hold a special shareholder meeting to vote on a resolution requesting the board of directors to accept the bidder’s proposal.  A prospective bidder who holds more than 1% could not avail itself of this provision unless it sold down to 1% before making the request.  The bidder would have to furnish an investment banker’s opinion addressed to the shareholders of the company that the price proposed by the bidder is fair.198

The shareholder meeting to vote on the proposed transaction would level the playing field by allowing both the bidder and company’s management to submit information concerning the fairness of the potential bid and alternatives thereto.199  And if “a majority of the company’s outstanding shares vote in favor of the resolution at the special shareholder meeting, the pill would be redeemed so as to permit consummation of the bidder’s proposal or a competing better proposal.”200  The new plan would also “assure sufficient time to consider the bidder’s proposal and to seek and evaluate alternatives,” by requiring the meeting to be held between 90 and 120 days after the bidder’s request.201  This proposal was built on key premises of the U.K. Approach to takeovers, which prevented boards from interfering with the ability of stockholders to accept fully financed, all shares, non-coercive bids, while building on Lipton’s view that a shareholder vote was less coercive than a tender offer.  Thus, the stockholders would vote first to redeem the pill without fearing that a no vote would have any effect on their ability to tender if the majority of stockholders voted to redeem the pill.  Lipton advocated for Congress to adopt legislation regulating the form of takeover bids along similar lines, and argued that if Congress adopted legislation like that, pills would not be needed.202

By providing for a stockholder vote, after full disclosure and deliberation, in exchange for the robust protections of the flip-in provision, Lipton’s second-generation plan struck a careful balance between shareholder democracy and preventing takeover abuses:

Thus, under conditions that ensure that a bidder is not abusing the tender offer process, the second generation pill allows the target’s shareholders to determine the fate of the company after disclosure of all relevant information and with sufficient time to consider and act on such information.203

Lipton viewed this as a worthwhile compromise, recognizing that if “the new pill channels takeover activity into the special shareholder meeting procedure, it will be more effective than the original pill in discouraging abusive takeover tactics and will provide more time for a target to deal with the cash offer for all shares against which there is today no practical defense other than drastic restructuring.”204  Lipton “recognize[d] that the new pill assures a raider that it can obtain a shareholder vote on a proposed takeover, and, therefore, might be said to promote takeovers,” on balance, “if universally adopted, the new pill would decrease substantially hostile takeover activity.”205

Thus, despite the potency of the new rights plan, its careful balancing of interests reflected the same intentions that had inspired the original rights plan years earlier:

The new pill does not prevent takeovers.  Like its predecessor it protects against the worst takeover abuses, it gives all parties a reasonable period of time in which to make decisions on such a fundamentally important question as a takeover, and it strengthens the ability of the board of directors of a target to obtain the best result for the shareholders.206

Although Lipton did not agree with Chancellor Allen’s Interco decision, the two had great respect and affection for each other. Here, they discuss Interco and Time-Warner at Penn in a session moderated by then Vice Chancellor, and long-time Penn faculty member, Leo Strine, Jr.

As he did with Takeover Bids nearly a decade before, Lipton also took the opportunity to introduce real-world data he viewed as supporting the adoption of rights plans.  His memorandum detailing the second-generation rights plan included an appendix showing 36 acquisitions of targets that had adopted first-generation rights plans, which featured an aggregate increase in consideration of $4.7 billion versus the initial bids made for those companies.207  Thus, although Lipton acknowledged that certain studies had found short-term reductions in stock prices associated with adopting rights plans, Lipton opined that “the plan clearly serves its principal objectives — protection against abusive tactics and increased bargaining power resulting in higher prices for shareholders.”208

In response to the stock market crash of October 1987, Lipton wrote that “[t]he overleveraged takeover and the short-term oriented speculative activity associated with the takeover frenzy of the eighties were, predictably, significant factors leading to the crash.”209  He nonetheless warned clients of additional creeping tender offers through open market accumulations of control positions, and noted that “[t]he best immediately available defense against a creeping takeover is the second generation share purchase rights plan with a 20% flip-in provision that may be amended to 15% or 10% to meet specific threats.  We recommend that all of our clients consider substituting the new plan to achieve this important protection for their shareholders.”210  In addition, he noted that the stock market decline “lowered stock market prices to a level where [companies] became attractive to corporate strategic buyers,” noting that the retreat of corporate raiders to the sidelines and lower market prices had “combined to make hostile bidders of acquirors who previously would undertake only a negotiated acquisition.”211

With his embrace of the flip-in pill, Lipton crossed another threshold.  Moving from an earlier reluctance to say that a target board could prevent stockholders from deciding for themselves whether to accept a non-coercive bid solely on the grounds that the board thought the price was too low, Lipton began to adopt a philosophy — using a coinage from First Lady Nancy Reagan’s anti-drug campaign — that boards should be able to use a pill to “Just Say No” on just that ground.  Thus, while retaining his long-standing view that a board should be able to block a bid that threatened the company’s workers, stakeholders or communities of operation, Lipton also now voiced the view that they could protect the stockholders from accepting a bid that the board viewed as undervaluing the company.    

With the Delaware courts having already held that the pill could be used to prevent a structurally coercive bid, this question of how far a board could go to use a pill to block a non-coercive, all shares offer would soon be the subject of great focus as the decade waned.

Interco and Pillsbury212

In 1988, some three years after Delaware accepted the facial validity of Lipton’s pill in Moran, the pill’s “as applied” usage was tested in two decisions by the Court of Chancery.  The attacks on the pill in Moran came on a “clear day,” and allowed the pill’s defenders to present it as the necessary antidote to the coerciveness of the two-tier tender offer then in vogue, often financed by the bidder in bootstrap fashion relying on the target’s own assets and presaging the bidder’s plan to “bust up” the target to repay the acquisition debt.  The judiciary’s acknowledgement that the poison pill could legitimately be employed to protect against the structural coercion of these bids led to a response from the hostile bidder side:  bidders began to present all-cash, all-shares offers where there was no threat of coercion, especially because courts had accepted pills with a “flip-in feature” that caused immediate dilution to the bidder if it crossed the relevant threshold (commonly 15% in this period) by its acquisition of the target’s shares.  By this period, Lipton, who had previously expressed concern about the validity of the flip-in feature as discussed above, had updated Wachtell Lipton’s own pill to include it, given the judicial acceptance of that assertive feature.

The lurking question that had always loomed — could a target board prevent stockholders from considering a non-coercive bid after the board has had a chance to negotiate and find a higher bid and to fully inform the stockholders of its position on the offer? — came to the fore.  In his earlier Takeover Bids in the Target’s Boardroom article, Lipton had not staked out the position that a target board could block a bid solely because it thought the price was too low.  By 1988, Lipton took the view that a poison pill could be used to stop a bid if the target board believed in good faith that the offer was too low or threatened the company’s other stakeholders.  Lipton’s construct viewed the corporation as a republic, and if stockholders wished to change policy, they should elect a new board; but stockholders could not directly override the board’s business judgment that a takeover was adverse to the company’s best interests.

In the two cases that came before the Court of Chancery in 1988, the question of who decides was squarely presented for the first time because the tender offer in the cases were fully financed all-cash/all-shares offers.  The boogeyman of the two-tier offer was absent, and price alone was the point of contention.

In the Interco case,213 decided on November 1, 1988, the court was presented with a motion for preliminary injunction by the bidder, the Rales brothers, who sought to require the target’s board of directors to remove its poison pill to allow the stockholders to decide for themselves whether to accept a $74 all-cash, all-shares tender offer with a promised prompt back-end merger at the same price if the tender offer were successful.  As an alternative to the tender offer, the board sought to implement unilaterally (without stockholder action) a complicated restructuring transaction that was believed (by the board) to have a value to stockholders of at least $76/share.  The company had not received a competing offer during the lengthy period since the Rales’ first offer, and the restructuring was the board’s only alternative.  The restructuring itself largely involved breaking up the company, selling one of its “Crown Jewels” (Ethan Allen), and leveraging up the remaining company in order to fund immediate payouts of cash and high coupon debt to stockholders.  The questions before Chancellor Allen involved whether the board’s own plan effectively put the company up for sale and required them to sell the company in an auction, and, most importantly, whether the board could stand behind the pill to block the Rales Brothers’ bid.

Only three days before the Interco decision, Lipton issued a memo titled “Is This the End of Takeovers?” calling the courts “our only hope”:

At the moment, the courts are our only hope.  The poison pill is an effective defense against abusive takeovers.  The courts are now recognizing this.  Hopefully, they will make it clear that a board of directors does not have to redeem a pill and either auction the company to the highest bidder or restructure by turning equity into debt.  In other words, the courts should affirm that a board of directors, acting in good faith and on reasonable grounds, has the absolute right to reject any takeover bid.  At other moments in our history, the courts have stepped in to solve social and economic problems that were beyond the Congress.  What is necessary today is that they defer to the honest business judgment of boards of directors.  While corporate raiders in league with institutional investors may shift from tender offers to proxy fights to force boards into auctions or restructuring, that shift will slow down the process, expose the role of the institutions and further the opportunity for legislation regulating the institutions.214

Lipton’s hopes were soon dashed.  In granting a mandatory injunction requiring the pill’s redemption, Chancellor Allen emphasized that the pill was no longer being used to increase options or value, but at an “end stage” to “protect the restructuring”:

It is significant that the question of the board’s responsibility to redeem or not to redeem the stock rights in this instance arises at what I will call the end-stage of this takeover contest.  That is, the negotiating leverage that a poison pill confers upon this company’s board will, it is clear, not be further utilized by the board to increase the options available to shareholders or to improve the terms of those options.  Rather, at this stage of this contest, the pill now serves the principal purpose of “protecting the restructuring” — that is, precluding the shareholders from choosing an alternative to the restructuring that the board finds less valuable to shareholders.

Accordingly, this case involves a further judicial effort to pick out the contours of a director’s fiduciary duty to the corporation and its shareholders when the board has deployed the recently innovated and powerful antitakeover device of flip-in or flip-over stock rights.  That inquiry is, of course, necessarily a highly particularized one.215

In applying the Unocal standard, Chancellor Allen posited that the Interco board believed in good faith in the higher value of its restructuring alternative while noting that that question was “inherently a debatable proposition”216 given that the value of the resulting stub shares was “unknowable with reasonable certainty”; that the board believed in good faith after prudent evaluation that the $74/share tender offer was inadequate; that the tender offer was “in no respect coercive”; and that the “utility” of the pill had been “effectively exhausted” save only to “protect the restructuring.”217   Chancellor Allen accepted that a board is not required to redeem a pill “simply by reason of the existence of a noncoercive offer,” since even then a tender offer may represent a “threat” to stockholder interests “in the special sense that an active negotiator with power, in effect, to refuse the proposal may be able to extract a higher or otherwise more valuable proposal, or may be able to arrange an alternative transaction or a modified business plan that will present a more valuable option to shareholders.”  But the Chancellor concluded that in the “highly particularized” circumstances presented, the poison pill could not be allowed to remain in place:

Our corporation law exists, not as an isolated body of rules and principles, but rather in a historical setting and as a part of a larger body of law premised upon shared values.  To acknowledge that directors may employ the recent innovation of “poison pills” to deprive shareholders of the ability effectively to choose to accept a noncoercive offer, after the board has had a reasonable opportunity to explore or create alternatives, or attempt to negotiate on the shareholders’ behalf, would, it seems to me, be so inconsistent with widely shared notions of appropriate corporate governance as to threaten to diminish the legitimacy and authority of our corporation law.218

At the same time, the Chancellor rejected the bidder’s argument that the restructuring was impermissible under the Revlon doctrine, noting that he did not read Revlon to require an “auction” or proscribe a board from implementing a defensive recapitalization if a board determined in good faith on an informed basis that the recapitalization is more beneficial to shareholders.  Importantly, he allowed Interco to sell Ethan Allen piecemeal and thus denied the Rales brothers the chance to buy it as a part of buying the entire company.

Interco was the first judicial application of Unocal to the pill in a real-time takeover case.  Interco immediately appealed to the Delaware Supreme Court but before the appeal could be heard, the Rales brothers withdrew their tender offer, presumably because the Ethan Allen sale upset their plans.  Interco remained independent, if a very different company, and the Supreme Court was denied an opportunity to speak to Chancellor Allen’s opinion.  

Interco was followed six weeks later (on December 16, 1988) by the decision in Pillsbury,219 likewise granting a mandatory preliminary injunction requiring a board to redeem a pill in the face of a fully financed all-cash, all-shares tender offer.  The opinion, by Justice Duffy (retired) sitting in Chancery by assignment, essentially followed the reasoning of Interco.  The decision further enjoined the target Pillsbury from spinning off its Burger King business or having Burger King pay a pre-spin dividend.The one-two punch of Interco and Pillsbury drew a strong response from Lipton.  Writing two days after Interco, Lipton called the opinion “a dagger aimed at the hearts of all Delaware corporations,” and suggested that the decision, coupled with Delaware’s failure to enact a strong antitakeover statute, raised a “very serious question” about incorporating in Delaware.  Wrote Lipton:  “Perhaps it is time to migrate out of Delaware”:

The Tuesday, November 1, decision in the Interco case came as a surprise. . .  The Delaware Chancery Court in Interco held that the company could not use its poison pill as a shield against the inadequate offer until it had completed the distribution to its shareholders of the dividend to be paid as part of its restructuring.  Rather, the Court said, after the restructuring plan has been developed and adopted, the pill must be redeemed so that the tender offer could go forward before the distribution.  This despite the fact that the Court found no fault with the restructuring plan and no reason to doubt that the Interco board reasonably concluded that the hostile tender offer was inadequate and that the restructuring plan was preferable.  Further, there was no finding of entrenchment — indeed, the restructuring plan did not roll up management’s shareholdings into a blocking position and Interco was as much subject to takeover after the restructuring as before.

While the Court in the Interco case pays lip service to the doctrines that companies do not have to have permanent for sale signs and that an auction sale is not the only response a target of a hostile cash bid for all its shares can make, the practical effect of the decision is just that.  I believe it flies in the face of the Delaware Supreme Court decisions [under the Unocal doctrine].  If it is not reversed by the Delaware Supreme Court, it will be a dagger aimed at the hearts of all Delaware corporations and a further fueling of the takeover frenzy.

The Interco case and the failure of Delaware to enact an effective takeover statute, raise a very serious question as to Delaware incorporation.  New Jersey, Ohio and Pennsylvania, among others, are far more desirable states for incorporation than Delaware in this takeover era.  Perhaps it is time to migrate out of Delaware.It should be noted that press reports to the contrary notwithstanding, the Interco case did not cast any doubt on the legality of the poison pill.  The pill remains the most effective means of dealing with abusive takeover tactics.  But unless Interco is reversed by the Delaware Supreme Court its benefits to targets and their shareholders will be significantly curtailed.220

The Pillsbury ruling drew an even fiercer response.  In a memo the day after the ruling — entitled “You Can’t Just Say No In Delaware No More” — Lipton characterized the Pillsbury ruling as “disastrous for American business and the American economy,” requiring companies to satisfy institutional investor and arbitrageur demands for “short-term stock price performance” and leading to leverage and decreased R&D investment that “will destroy [the ability of Delaware corporations] to compete in world markets”:

The Pillsbury decision yesterday fulfills the threat to Delaware corporations presaged by the Interco decision.  In Pillsbury a single Delaware judge substituted his judgment for the business judgment of the Pillsbury Board of Directors and sentenced Pillsbury to death as an independent company.  The death sentence was passed despite the fact that the Pillsbury Board was not found to be acting in bad faith or negligently and despite the fact that the Pillsbury Board, on the advice of independent investment bankers, had determined that the takeover bid on the table was inadequate and was asking for $5 per share more as the price for a negotiated merger.

The Pillsbury decision confirms the fear that the Delaware judges have abandoned the Business Judgment Rule in takeover cases and will substitute their business judgment for that of a target company’s board of directors, even though the board is acting in good faith and on a reasonable basis.

The effect of the Pillsbury decision will be disastrous for American business and the American economy.  It will fuel the takeover frenzy.  It guarantees that any highest cash bid for all the shares of a company will result in the bidder acquiring the target.  It even threatens the effective use of the poison pill as a means of achieving the time and circumstances necessary for a target’s board to obtain the highest value for the shareholders.  The Pillsbury decision means that the constant threat of takeover will be ever present for Delaware corporations, and, to survive, they will have to satisfy the demands of institutional investors and arbitrageurs for short-term stock price performance by increasing their leverage to dangerous levels and decreasing research, development and capital investment to levels that will ultimately destroy their ability to compete in world markets.The Pillsbury decision shows that Delaware either does not understand, or does not care about, the long-range macroeconomic problems of the takeover frenzy and the concomitant deequitization of American business and its forced refocus on short-range stock market performance.  Unless Delaware acts quickly to correct the Pillsbury decision, the only avenues open to the half of major American companies incorporated in Delaware will be federal legislation of the type now being considered by the Treasury Department or leaving Delaware for a more hospitable state of incorporation.221

These two Lipton memos occupy a special place in the never-ending dialogue between Lipton and Delaware.  The Interco memo was famously described in one article with the introduction:  “Then Marty Roared.”222  The same article notes Lipton’s further comments a few months later in a widely circulated article:

Delaware has misled corporate America.… It lured companies in with a promise that the business-judgment rule would govern corporate law.  It’s obvious that the state has reneged.223

Lipton continued to innovate and advocate for poison pill Rights Plans and variants notwithstanding Interco and Pillsbury.  Lipton’s creativity was undiminished and undeterred.  Within a month of Interco, Lipton announced a “new strategy to deal with takeovers — Share Price Repurchase Rights,” which he described as specially crafted to alleviate the pressure from institutional investors to “leverage or die” and thereby enhance the short-term share price:

We have developed a new strategy to deal with takeovers — Share Price Protection Repurchase Rights (“repo rights”).  They are particularly appropriate for successful companies whose shares are undervalued and who are under pressure to restructure.  They telegraph to the market a company’s confidence in its future and they are an incentive to institutional investors to be long-term shareholders.

At the time we developed the basic flip-over and flip-in share purchase rights plan, we also developed a rights plan that was designed to assure non-tendering shareholders the right to sell their shares back to the company at a price set by the board of directors.  Forms of this “put” plan were used successfully by Phillips Petroleum and Revlon, but put rights have fallen into disuse in the last few years.  The nature and extent of takeover activity this year gives rise to reconsideration of put rights in a different form and context from the Phillips and Revlon varieties.

As originally used the put right was issued by the target after a tender offer had been made at an inadequate price.  The original put right gave shareholders — other than the raider — the right to put their shares to the target at a specified price in excess of the tender offer price if the raider purchased more than a specified percentage of the outstanding shares.  Thus, the original put right was a value enhancement device designed to assure nontendering shareholders the value of their shares as determined by the board of directors, rather than the price offered by the raider.

The basic flip-over, flip-in right is more flexible than the put right, does not impact the balance sheet and does not put a price on the company.  For these and other reasons it became the universally accepted means to stop abusive and inadequate takeovers and level the playing field.  It has performed these functions well.  Two-tier tender offers, creeping tender offers and street sweeps have virtually been eliminated by the flip-over, flip-in right.  In addition, it has proven to be very effective in providing time to enable targets to maximize shareholder value.224

In his “personal observations” published on the occasion of the pill’s quinquennial anniversary, in a memo of January 10, 1989 entitled “Progenitor’s Retrospective — The Poison Pill at Five,” Lipton concluded by noting that the Delaware Supreme Court had not addressed “Just Say No,” and that, thus, “hope remains”:

The soon to occur fifth birthday of the poison pill prompts these personal observations:

  • It is one of the all-time most successful legal-financial innovations.
  • Close to 1000 companies have adopted it.
  • It has proven to work exactly as it was designed to work.
  • The Chicago School economists who argued that it would stop all takeovers have been proven wrong.
  • It has virtually eliminated two-tier tender offers, street sweeps and other abusive takeover tactics.
  • Adoption is neutral with respect to the market price of the company’s stock.
  • It has levelled the playing field and restored to the board of directors the ability to seek and achieve the best deal for the shareholders.
  • As was so aptly noted in the Federated Department Stores case, it is a “shield” against takeover abuses and a “gavel” that can be used to get the highest price.
  • Its basic legality has been sustained in court (although the flip-in provision has run into some trouble) and several states have enacted statutes that specifically authorize it.
  • The law firms that argued that it was illegal have been proven wrong and all of them now routinely advise clients that it is legal.
  • Although they continue, the efforts of the Council of Institutional Investors and CREF to kill it by soliciting proxies for anti-pill resolutions have failed.
  • While the Delaware Chancery Court has held that it cannot be used in a “just say no” defense, the Delaware Supreme Court has not yet addressed the issue and hope remains that it will recognize that a board of directors may properly determine that a company should remain independent.225

Lipton’s “hope” would soon come closer to fulfillment in a case that did not involve the poison pill, but would be influenced by the Delaware Supreme Court’s first opportunity to speak about Interco:  the landmark battle over the future of Time Inc.

Time/Warner and QVC:  The Delaware Supreme Court Speaks226

It was not only Lipton who was frustrated by their having been no appeals in the Interco and Pillsbury cases.  According to a controversial article that contained quotations, on and off the record, from members of the Court of Chancery and the Delaware Supreme Court, some members of the Supreme Court were disappointed they had not had a chance to speak to the question of whether a board could use a pill to block a bid solely on price grounds and because the board believed that another strategic option was preferable.  In the article, Lipton’s frustrations over Interco and Pillsbury were recounted.227

To the casual observer, it appeared that Wachtell argued opposite sides of the same issue in Paramount v. Time Warner in 1989 and Paramount v. QVC in 1993. In fact, the two matters established precedents that make up the “bookends” of Delaware take-over law.

In the following spring and summer of 1989, the Delaware Supreme Court would find an opportunity to have its say, albeit in a case that did not turn on the use of a poison pill.  The case involved a challenge to a proposed merger in which Time Inc. — the iconic publisher of Time Magazine and formerly of Life Magazine and by the 1980s, also of People Magazine — sought to merge with Warner Communications.  The merger was the product of an extensive study by Time’s board, which had looked at other alternatives, and involved the view that Time needed scale and to have content not just in the print space, but in the movie, television, and music space, and to take advantage of that content on Time’s cable television markets.  Time’s board was populated with blue-chip members of America’s business and academic establishment.

When the merger was announced, the markets liked it and Time’s price rose, even though it was using its stock to acquire Warner and paying a premium to market.  In its announcement of the deal, Time lauded that one of the major values of the transaction was that it did not increase the company’s debt and that the resulting combined company could invest more substantially in future growth.  But then things got interesting.  Another industry player and competitor of Warner’s, Paramount Communication, offered to buy Time itself for $175 per share, nearly $50 a share over the price at which the stock market was valuing the Time-Warner combination.  Paramount then raised its bid to $200 per share.

The Time board refused to even negotiate with Paramount and stuck to its view that a combination with Warner was the optimal path.  To defeat the Paramount offer, Time recut its deal with Paramount so that it was paying cash to Warner’s stockholders, a 56% premium that resulted in the company having to take on substantial leverage and erasing the debt-free benefits for the original transaction form.  The reason for the change was simple and singular — Time’s stockholders had to vote on the original stock-for-stock transaction under the rules of the New York Stock Exchange — and the board of Time knew they could not obtain approval because of stockholder appetite to accept Paramount’s bid.  And to get Warner’s stockholders to accept cash rather than stock, Time was asked to pay a much higher premium and it agreed to do so.

Paramount sued in Chancery seeking to enjoin the newly cut merger under the Revlon and Unocal doctrines.  In a nuanced decision, Chancellor Allen found that Revlon was not implicated because Time was acquiring Warner in a merger in which there would be no resulting change of control, and that control of Time would continue to rest “in a large, fluid, changeable and changing market.”  For that reason, Chancellor Allen held that Time’s board was under no duty to accept the alternative that would produce the highest immediate value, as would have been the case if Time were engaging in a change of control transaction, but could govern the company with the view to the stockholders’ long-term best interests.  He also rejected the Unocal claim that the board’s reaction to the Paramount offer to recut the Warner merger was unreasonable.228

Herbert Wachtell gave a congratulatory hug to fellow Wachtell Lipton attorney Barbara Robbins after the Delaware Supreme Court upheld a ruling that allowed QVC to bid on a level playing field for Paramount.

Chancellor Allen found that the Time board had studied the merger with Warner long before any threat of a bid came on the scene, that the board was independent and believed that the merger would be more valuable in the long-run than the $200 bid.  He ruled that because the board was merely reacting to the threat of the Paramount bid by acting to consummate a transaction within the board’s statutory power, its actions were reasonable and survived Unocal scrutiny, despite the stark gap between the board’s view of value and that of the stock market.   Suggesting that he was more than a little aware of the large gap between the board’s view of value and that of most objective observers, Chancellor Allen noted that the projection by the company’s bankers that Time-Warner shares would trade between $ 208 and $402 in the out years, after the merger was a “range that a Texan might feel at home on.”229

In his ultimate ruling, Chancellor Allen stressed that under corporate law, directors had broad leeway to exercise their powers in good faith while in office, and that although the results may not always turn out optimally, there were advantages to this system:  “[J]ust as the Constitution does not enshrine Mr. Herbert Spencer’s social statics, neither does the common law of directors’ duties elevate the theory of a single, efficient capital market to the dignity of a sacred text.  Directors may operate on the theory that the stock market valuation is ‘wrong’ in some sense, without breaching faith with shareholders.”230

The Chancellor also noted that for diversified investors, much of the value they received depended on managerial innovation and risk-taking and that courts should be reluctant to intrude upon it:

The value of a shareholder’s investment, over time, rises or falls chiefly because of the skill, judgment and perhaps luck-for it is present in all human affairs-of the management and directors of the enterprise.  When they exercise sound or brilliant judgment, shareholders are likely to profit; when they fail to do so, share values likely will fail to appreciate. In either event, the financial vitality of the corporation and the value of the company’s shares is in the hands of the directors and managers of the firm.  The corporation law does not operate on the theory that directors, in exercising their powers to manage the firm, are obligated to follow the wishes of a majority of shares. In fact, directors, not shareholders, are charged with the duty to manage the firm.

In the decision they have reached here, the Time board may be proven in time to have been brilliantly prescient or dismayingly wrong. In this decision, as in other decisions affecting the financial value of their investment, the shareholders will bear the effects for good or ill.  That many, presumably most, shareholders would prefer the board to do otherwise than it has done does not, in the circumstances of a challenge to this type of transaction, in my opinion, afford a basis to interfere with the effectuation of the board’s business judgment.231

Herbert Wachtell spoke to members of the press outside of the courthouse during the 1993 Paramount v. QVC matter.

At the same, in ruling for Time, Chancellor Allen was careful to note that for reasons of timing, the poison pill that Time had in place was not the focus of his decision and not at issue.  To Chancellor Allen, a board’s decision to pursue a merger for business reasons stood on a different and more legitimate footing than the use of a rights plan, the only utility of which was to block stockholders from accepting a bid, especially one that was, in the case of Paramount’s, all-cash, all-shares, and thus non-coercive.  Thus, Chancellor Allen ended his opinion with a key footnote caveat:  “[I]n my view, a decision not to redeem a poison pill, which by definition is a control mechanism and not a device with independent business purposes, may present distinctive considerations than those presented in this case.”232 

On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court issued a less nuanced opinion that contained several stark pronouncements.233

The Supreme Court affirmed Chancellor Allen’s Revlon ruling, albeit on other grounds.  The Court held that Time’s agreement to the Warner merger did not trigger any Revlon duty to seek short-term value, noting that Revlon was implicated only if the corporation initiated a bidding process to sell itself or effect “a clear break-up of the company,” or chose to abandon a long-term strategy in favor of an alternative that involves the break-up of the company.234

Turning to Unocal, the Supreme Court also affirmed but for reasons that went well beyond Chancellor Allen’s carefully cabined words.  The Supreme Court declared that the board’s statutory mandate to manage the business and affairs of the corporation “includes a conferred authority to set a corporate course of action, including time frame, designed to enhance corporate profitability.”235  Under the Supreme Court’s analysis, if a corporate plan was determined by directors in good faith and advisedly to be in the corporation’s best interests, the directors seemingly could never be obliged to set it aside in favor of short-term higher values.

The Time/Warner fact pattern did not involve a poison pill but it did present what the Supreme Court called “structural safety devices” more commonly known as deal protections, such as a no-shop and a mutual share-exchange premium that were subject to Unocal review.  It was on this point that the Supreme Court spoke most favorably to director power and entitlement.  Canvassing Chancery’s development of Delaware doctrine in the preceding period, the Supreme Court focused on Chancery’s embrace of the proposition that an all-cash, all-shares tender at a price that shareholders might find attractive could not constitute a Unocal threat sufficient to justify much in the way of a defensive response.  That perspective — which underlay Interco and Pillsbury — was unequivocally rejected by the Supreme Court as “narrow and rigid” — as a “fundamental misconception of our standard of review under Unocal principally because it would involve the court in substituting its judgment as to what is a ‘better’ deal for that of a corporation’s board of directors.”  The Court stated it rejected Interco “and its progeny.”236  This scathing statement, while dictum and arguably not accounting for the actual reasoning of those decisions, sent a huge message.  Notably, the Court chose to characterize those decisions as improperly involving the “the court” in deciding what was the “‘better’ deal” while Chancery’s opinions in those cases had held that stockholders(not the court) should decide after a target board presented with a non-coercive offer had adequate time to develop alternatives and tell its story.   

The Supreme Court’s view, simply stated, was that a board could foreclose stockholder choice and pursue its own strategic direction — perhaps the strongest statement from Delaware of a director-centric view of corporate power.  Indeed, the Supreme Court took the view that it was legitimate for the Time board to take into account that the Time stockholders might decide to tender “in ignorance or a mistaken belief of the strategic benefit which a business combination with Warner might produce.”237  The Court viewed this threat of self-inflicted stockholder error as somehow separate from the board’s view that the $200 offer was too low and did not point to any lack of available information that could render stockholders unable to choose.  Rather, the Court took the position that the Board could take the paternalistic perspective that it knew best.  The argument that it was an unreasonable response to preclude stockholder choice was dispatched as “a fundamental misunderstanding of where the power of corporate governance lies” — which the Court held included the duty of “selection of a time frame for achievement of corporate goals.”238  In a ringing endorsement of director prerogatives, the Court stated:  “Directors are not obliged to abandon a deliberately conceived corporate plan for a short-term shareholder profit unless there is clearly no basis to sustain the corporate strategy.”239

Lipton, understandably, applauded the Time/Warner opinion that embedded so much of his fundamental concepts into Delaware doctrine.  In a brief memo the day after the opinion — entitled “Delaware Says Yes To Just Say No” — Lipton elided over the absence of a pill in the case, taking what may have been dicta, strictly speaking, as the new Delaware paradigm:

The opinion in Time-Warner is a ringing endorsement of the Just Say No response to a hostile tender offer.  The Delaware Supreme court has rejected Pillsbury and Interco and made it clear a company can remain independent even in the face of an adequate all cash tender offer.  In the words of the Delaware Court: “Directors are not obliged to abandon a deliberately conceived corporate plan for a short-term shareholder profit unless there is clearly no basis to sustain the corporate strategy.240

The Time/Warner opinion and the reach of its dictum would remain important to the evolution of Delaware’s takeover/fiduciary duty doctrine.

The next major case in which the Delaware Supreme Court spoke to takeovers underscored Lipton’s pragmatism.  The Revlon doctrine, while strongly critiqued by Lipton when the case was first decided, had become entrenched.  By the 1990s, structurally coercive bids were rare, and most M&A resulted from voluntary decisions of management to sell the company or (as in Time-Warner) to do a strategic merger.  Lipton’s basic view of director prerogatives readily encompassed about mergers motivated by directorial/managerial beliefs that the entities involved would improve their performance in combination.

And so the next case to come before the Delaware Supreme Court saw Lipton and Wachtell Lipton representing a topping bidder in a situation when a target company had already voluntarily entered into a merger agreement that would dramatically change the profile of the company and alter its board’s (and its stockholders’) ability to chart its future.  In 1994, Wachtell Lipton represented Barry Diller’s QVC in making an interloping offer to buy Paramount, which had already signed a merger agreement to combine with Sumner Redstone’s Viacom.  Paramount was the same company that lost in Time-Warner and it was not to end up any happier this time around.241

Paramount had structured its deal with Viacom seemingly to take advantage of the supposedly narrowed view of Revlon’s applicability that the Supreme Court had relied upon in Time/Warner.  Because the Paramount stockholders would receive stock, and because the Paramount board had carefully studied the deal with Viacom and thought it would provide great long-term value to the Paramount stockholders, Paramount took the position that it did not have to sell to the highest bidder because Revlon was not applicable.  QVC argued to the contrary, stressing the reasoning of Chancellor Allen’s trial-level decision in Time, and the fact that the combined company would have a controlling stockholder because Redstone, the controller of Viacom, would own a majority of the voting stock.  With a controlling stockholder, QVC argued through Wachtell Lipton, control of Paramount was shifting from the public stockholders to a particular controller, and thus Revlon applied.   

In ruling in favor of QVC, the Supreme Court brushed aside Paramount’s reliance upon its Time/Warner opinion and its assertion that the transaction was a strategic merger not subject to Revlon review because it involved no corporate breakup or decision to sell, but was a strategic, stock-for-stock merger.  The Court (affirming Chancery’s conclusion that Revlon applied) found the Paramount board’s process “deficient” and labeled their Time/Warner defense an “empty rationalization.”242  The Court held that the Paramount-Viacom combination was a sale of control, distinguishing Time as a circumstance where there was no change of control in the original stock-for-stock merger agreement between Time and Warner given that the resulting combined company “would be owned by a fluid aggregation of unaffiliated stockholders.”243  Thus, the QVC Supreme Court embraced Chancellor Allen’s reasoning in Time/Warner.  Because Viacom’s controlling stockholder (Redstone) would end up with control of the combined company, relegating the Paramount stockholders to minority status in a company with a controlling stockholder.  As a result, the Court reasoned:  “Irrespective of the present Paramount Board’s vision of a long-term strategic alliance with Viacom, the proposed sale of control would provide the new controlling stockholder with the power to alter that vision.”244  The Paramount board, at bottom, had made a category error by thinking that Time/Warner shielded its actions.

The rest of the QVC decision followed logically from that critical shift from a context where the board was empowered to decide what was best in the long-term, from one where the board had to seek the highest value reasonably attainable.  Rather than responding to QVC’s interloping, topping bid by trying to put Viacom and QVC on a level playing field and seeking to extract the highest price, Paramount had reacted by extracting a higher price from Viacom but also simultaneously agreeing to a host of very strong deal protection measures that, instead of facilitating competition, were designed to block QVC and ensure that the favored bidder, Viacom, would succeed.  The Court thus found the defensive measures unreasonable under Unocal, and affirmed the Court of Chancery’s injunction of the stock option and break-up fees.  In so ruling, the Supreme Court stressed that neither Revlon nor Unocal prevented boards from exercising their reasonable judgment about the use of deal protection measures, and that a variety of potential course of action could be reasonable.245  In underscoring the connection between the business judgment rule and heightened scrutiny, the Court took a view Lipton had strongly advocated:  that directors in the M&A context had to be allowed the freedom to make difficult judgments, and that if they did so in good faith and reasonably, the courts should defer.  Here, because the deal protections were used to end, rather than facilitate, the Paramount board’s duty under Revlon to seek the highest immediate value reasonably attainable, the Court could not defer.  After the injunction, the bidding process continued in see-saw fashion between QVC and Viacom.  Ultimately, Viacom triumphed albeit at a much higher price that QVC chose not to exceed. 

The QVC opinion provoked some consternation over whether Delaware was now tilting in a pro-bidder path, and, in particular, whether that movement had been as a result of Wachtell Lipton’s successful litigation on behalf (unusually) of a deal-jumping unsolicited bid.  Lipton issued a memo within days of QVC (February 7, 1994) — entitled “Ten Questions Raised by Paramount.”246  The memo dissected the opinion to underscore that, in fact, Delaware had not moved in a pro-bidder or anti-board direction:

The Paramount decision issued by the Delaware Supreme Court last Friday answers a number of questions that come up in structuring an acquisition or responding to a takeover bid:  

1. Question.  If the sale of a company is for cash, or securities other than voting stock in a public company that does not have a control group, what standard should be followed by the board of directors. 

Answer.  The Paramount decision holds that in a sale of control context the directors of the company have one primary objective — “to secure the transaction offering the best value reasonably available for the stockholders.”  See Question 5 below.

2. Question.  Did Paramount hold that the poison pill is illegal?

Answer.  No.  Paramount did not invalidate the pill.  To the contrary it cites approvingly the Household decision in which the pill was first sustained by the Delaware Supreme Court. 

3. Question.  Can the target of a hostile takeover bid still just say no?

Answer.  Yes.  The Paramount decision expressly states that it does not apply to a situation where a company is following its own strategic plan and has not initiated a takeover situation.  Where the target of a hostile bid wishes to consider rejecting the bid and remaining independent it is critical that the board of directors follow the correct process and have the advice of an experienced investment banker and legal counsel.  The Paramount decision lists the key considerations for the board weighing an acquisition or a takeover: 

(a) the offer’s fairness and feasibility,

(b) the proposed financing,

(c) the consequences of the financing,

(d) questions of illegality,

(e) the risk of nonconsummation,

(f) the bidder’s identity, prior background and other business experiences, and

(g) the bidder’s business plans for the company and their effects on all stockholder interests.

4. Question.  If it is not a sale of control but rather a common stock merger with the combined company being a true public company, can you have no-shop and lock-up provisions? 

Answer.  Yes.  The Paramount decision is expressly limited to the situation of a sale of control.  It does not apply to the merger of two companies that results in a public company without a control group.  However, the Paramount decision does have much to say about the reasonableness of no-shop and lock-up provisions.  In light of the Paramount decision a no-shop provision that is limited to the company not initiating discussions with third parties but does not restrict responses to third-party initiatives is indicated.  A lock-up option or bust-up fee should also be reasonable in amount and not so material as to foreclose a third party bid.  The decision indicates that a combination of a lock-up stock option and a bust-up fee that is not capped at an aggregate reasonable amount is likely to be held invalid.  Also questionable are a put alternative to a lock-up stock option as is an alternative permitting noncash exercise.  While it can be argued that the Paramount decision discussion of lock-up options, bust-up fees and no­shop provisions is limited to sale of control situations, the underlying theme of the decision signals caution.  This is an area where more may well be less and too much may taint the independence of the board and jeopardize the deal. 

5. Question.  Is there any way to do a deal that is viewed as a sale of control without shopping or conducting an auction? 

Answer.  Yes.  If on the basis of well-considered expert advice the board determines it is more likely to get the best value reasonably available by not shopping or auctioning, then the board can authorize the transaction.  In this situation the board should document the basis for its determination and should avoid any no-shop, lock-up option of bust-up fee provision that would impede a third party from competing.  In the past the Delaware courts have approved a subsequent “market check” as a substitute for shopping prior to entering into an agreement and the Paramount decision does not reject that approach. 

6. Question.  In evaluating competing bids involving securities can the board decide that it prefers one security over the other?

Answer.  Yes, but only within reasonable limits.  The Paramount decision says, “a board of directors is not limited to considering only the amount of cash involved, and is not required to ignore totally its view of the future value of a strategic alliance. . . .  When assessing the value of non-cash consideration, a board should focus on its value as of the date it will be received by the stockholders.  Normally, such value will be determined with the assistance of experts using generally accepted methods of valuation.”  (Emphasis added).

7. Question.  Does the Paramount decision change the role or duties of the directors?

Answer.  No.  The court in the Paramount decision cited with approval the prior Delaware cases which basically say that in acquisition transactions the directors must be especially diligent.  The decision goes on to say “the role of outside, independent directors becomes particularly important because of the magnitude of a sale of control transaction and the possibility, in certain cases, that management may not necessarily be impartial.”

8. Question.  Can a company enter into a merger of equals (that is not a sale of control) in which neither company gets a premium?

Answer.  Yes.  The language in the Paramount decision that the shareholders of the acquired company must get a premium for the sale of control is expressly limited to the sale of control situations and does not apply to a merger of equals. 

9. Question.  If a company enters into a strategic merger that is not a sale of control in which the company gets a premium and a third party makes a hostile takeover bid for the company at a higher value to its shareholders, can the company cancel the merger and reject the hostile bid? 

Answer.  Yes, in theory, but as a practical matter there may be so much shareholder pressure that the company will be forced into the auction mode and be forced to accept the highest bid. 

10. Question.  In a transaction where it is permitted to use a bust-up fee, what is a reasonable amount? Answer.  The Paramount decision rejects an “unreasonable” bust-up fee but does not give guidance as to what is reasonable.  Prior precedent and the Paramount decision’s rejection of a $100 million bust-up fee as unreasonable when considered together with a lock-up option with a value of more than $400 million in a $10 billion transaction, provides some basis for the view that a bust-up fee of up to 2% is sustainable.247

Market dynamics proceeded to respond to the development of Delaware takeover doctrine.  The Delaware courts had signaled that deal protections even in stock-for-stock mergers were subject to Unocal review, and it became clear that the sell-side stockholders would not typically vote for a lower priced transaction when a higher bid was available.  Companies themselves become the primary initiators of M&A, and the announcement of voluntary mergers invited, a la QVC, other interested bidders to come forward and top.  As a century ended, most mergers were motivated by strategic business advantages and not by financial gimmickry, and boards of directors, and not financially motivated raiders, were the driving force for most transactions.  Director power had been vindicated by the courts, but increasingly that power was wielded to do deals, not fight them.


61 Martin Lipton, ‘Greenmail’ Is a Corporate Disgrace, N.Y. Times, Apr. 15, 1984 (quoting Lipton’s Congressional testimony from March 1984).
62 Martin Lipton & Andrew R. Brownstein, Takeover Responses and Directors’ Responsibilities: An Update 8-1(Dec. 1983).
63 Martin Lipton & Patricia A. Vlahakis, Securities Regulation Institute, Takeover Responses – 1984 Developments, U.C. San Diego Sec. Reg. Inst. 1 (Nov. 1984).
64 The Effect of Mergers on Management Practices, Cost, Availability of Credit, and the Long-Term Viability of American Industry: Hearing, Before the S. Subcomm. on Sec. of the Banking, Hous., & Urban Affairs, 99th Cong. 8 (1985) (statement of Martin Lipton).
65 Statement of Martin Lipton, 99th Cong. 8, 15.
66 Takeover Tactics and Public Policy: Hearings on H.R. 2371, H.R. 5250, H.R. 5693, H.R. 5694, H.R. 5695, and H.R. 5696 Before the H.R. Subcomm. on the Telecomm., Consumer Prot., & Fin. of the Comm. on Energy & Commerce, 98th Cong. 157 (1984) (statement of Martin Lipton).
67 Statement of Martin Lipton, 98th Cong. 160.
68 Martin Lipton, Takeover Bids in the Target’s Boardroom, 35 Bus. L. 101, 109-12 (1979).
69 Statement of Martin Lipton, 98th Cong. 156.
70 See Statement of Martin Lipton, 98th Cong. 157 (proposing solution to takeover abuses “based in large measure on the rules of the City Takeover Panel in the United Kingdom”); see also Statement of Martin Lipton, 99th Cong.; Tender Offer Reform Act of 1987: Hearing on H.R.1601 Before the H. Subcomm. on Telecomm. & Fin. of the H. Comm. on Energy & Commerce, 100th Cong. (1987) (statement of Martin Lipton).
71 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983). This first version of the plan was structured as a preferred stock dividend, but was functionally similar to later versions that issued rights, rather than preferred stock, as dividends.
72 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 1.
73 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 1-2.
74 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 1.
75 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 3.
76 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 5.
77 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 6.
78 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 6.
79 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 8.
80 Memo: Flip-In Rights Plans (May 30, 1986). (noting that Wachtell Lipton has not recommended flip-in pills “out of fear that a court would find that it was illegal and that it tainted the validity of the whole rights plan”).
81 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (June 20, 1983), at 2.
82 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (Aug. 17, 1983), at 1 (emphasis added) The early version of the plan, which was effected via an issuance of preferred stock with a “flip-over” provision, soon evolved into a similar plan in which the same protections “can be achieved by the declaration of a dividend consisting of rights to purchase common stock,” which rights “have a ‘flip-over’ provision similar in concept to that of the ‘poison pill’ convertible preferred stock.” Lipton & Vlahakis, Securities Regulation Institute, Takeover Responses – 1984 Developments, at 32-33.
83 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (Aug. 17, 1983), at 1, Annex II.
84 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (Aug. 17, 1983)
85 Nat’l Educ. Corp. v. Bell & Howell Co., 1983 WL 18035, at *5 (Del. Ch. Aug. 25, 1983).
86 Memo: Takeovers: The Convertible Preferred Stock Dividend Plan (Aug. 17, 1983), at 1. The Court later denied a motion to dismiss the litigation for failure to join the owners of the issued shares as necessary parties, noting that doing so would unjustly “insulate the provisions of such preferred stock from judicial attack by the simple expediency of issuing them pro rata to common shareholders as a stock dividend before the matter could be presented to a court for a determination.” Nat’l Educ. Corp. v. Bell & Howell Co., 1983 WL 8946, at *2 (Del. Ch. Dec. 13, 1983).
87 Frank Allen & Steve Swartz, Lenox Rebuffs Brown-Forman, Adopts Defense, Wall St. J., June 16, 1983.
88 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plan: An Update and a New Plan (July 24, 1987), at 1.
89 See, e.g., Memo: Poison Pills – Flip-Ins (Apr. 18, 1986); Memo: Poison Pill Again Upheld (Nov. 11, 1986); Memo: The Attack on the Poison Pill (Nov. 24, 1986); Memo: The Pill in Action (Mar. 14, 1988); Memo: Progenitor’s Retrospective – The Poison Pill at Five (Jan. 10, 1989).
90 Huffington v. ENSTAR Corp., 1984 WL 8209, at *3 (Del. Ch. Apr. 25, 1984).
91 Moran, 500 A.2d 1346 (Del. 1985).
92 For more information about the litigation of Unocal and the remembrances of key participants in the litigation, see the narrative video on the case, recorded interviews of participants, and opinions, briefs, and other materials from the case, at Unocal Video, Penn Law, The Delaware Corporation Law Resource Center.
93 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 949.
94 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 949.
95 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954.
96 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954 (contrasting the position the Court was taking from that of scholars like Easterbrook and Fischel).
97 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954 n.8.
98 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954 n.9.
99 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954.
100 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954.
101 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 955.
102 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 955 (“[S]uch proof is materially enhanced . . . by the approval of a board comprised of a majority of outside independent directors who have acted in accordance with the foregoing standards”).
103 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 955-56 & n.11 (citing Martin Lipton, Takeover Bids in the Target’s Boardroom, 35 Bus. Law. 101, at 113-14 (1979)).
104 For more information about the litigation of Moran and the remembrances of key participants in the litigation, see the narrative video on the case, recorded interviews of participants, and opinions, briefs, and other materials from the case, at Moran, Penn Law, The Delaware Corporation Law Center.
105 Moran v. Household Int’l, Inc., 490 A.2d 1059 (Del. Ch. 1985).
106 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 957.
107 Moran v. Household Int’l, Inc., 500 A.2d 1346, 1352 (Del. 1985) (citing Unocal, 493 A.2d at 957).
108 Moran, 500 A.2d at 1352.
109 Moran, 500 A.2d at 1348.
110 Moran, 500 A.2d at 1349.
111 Moran, 500 A.2d at 1354.
112 Moran, 500 A.2d at 1354-57.
113 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plans (“Poison Pills”) (Nov. 21, 1985).
114 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plans (“Poison Pills”) (Nov. 21, 1985).
115 Et Tu, Delaware?, Wall St. J., Nov. 21, 1985, at 30
116 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plans (“Poison Pills”) (Nov. 21, 1985), at 1.
117 For more information about the litigation of Revlon and the remembrances of key participants in the litigation, see the narrative video on the case, recorded interviews of participants, and opinions, briefs, and other materials from the case, at Revlon, Penn Law, The Delaware Corporation Law Resource Center.
118 Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 176 (Del. 1986).
119 Revlon, 506 A.2d at 181.
120 Revlon, 506 A.2d at 181.
121 Revlon, 506 A.2d at 182.
122 Revlon, 506 A.2d at 182.
123 See Takeover Boom of the 1980’s Narrative Video, Penn Law, at 57:38, The Delaware Corporation Law Resource Center.
124 Revlon, 506 A.2d at 182.
125 Memo: Takeover Issues for 1987 (Oct. 13, 1986), at 2.
126 For a discussion of second generation state takeover laws following Revlon, see Martin Lipton & Morris Panner, Takeover Bids and United States Corporate Governance, in Contemporary Issues in Corporate Governance 123-26 (D.D. Prentice & P.R.J. Holland eds., 1993).
127 Memo: Lockups (Jan. 8, 1986).
128 William Meyers, Showdown in Delaware: The Battle to Shape Takeover Law, Institutional Inv., Feb. 1989, at 71.
129 Memo: Takeovers – Where Do We Go From Here (June 18, 1986), at 2.
130 Memo: Takeover Issues for 1987 (Oct. 13, 1986).
131 Memo: The Poison Pill on the First Anniversary of Household (Nov. 19, 1986), at 1.
132 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 1.
133 Memo: Takeover Response Checklist (Nov. 23, 1988), at 1.
134 Memo: Flip-In Rights Plans (May 30, 1986).
135 Memo: Flip-In Rights Plans (May 30, 1986).
136 Memo: Flip-In Rights Plans (May 30, 1986).
137 Martin Lipton & Andrew R. Brownstein, Takeover Responses: An Update, 24th Annual Corporate Counsel Institute (Oct. 9-10, 1985), at 44.
138 Lipton & Brownstein, Takeover Responses: An Update, at 45
139 Amalgamated Sugar Co., LLC v. NL Indus., Inc., 644 F. Supp. 1229, 1234 (S.D.N.Y. 1986).
140 Amalgamated Sugar Co., LLC v. NL Indus., Inc., 644 F. Supp. 1229, 1237, 1238 (S.D.N.Y. 1986).
141 Memo: Shareholder Rights Plans After NL (Aug. 14, 1986).
142 Memo: Takeover Issues for 1987 (Oct. 13, 1986), at 2.
143 Memo: Shareholder Rights Plans After NL (Aug. 14, 1986).
144 Memo: Takeover Issues for 1987 (Oct. 13, 1986), at 2.
145 Memo: Shareholder Rights Plans After NL (Aug. 14, 1986).
146 Dynamics Corp. of Am. v. CTS Corp., 805 F.2d 705 (7th Cir. 1986).
147 Memo: Basic Concept of Poison Pill Sustained in Second CTS Case (Nov. 6, 1986).
148 Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of the Law (1st ed. 1973).
149 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance: Major Issues for the 1990s, Address to the Third Annual Corporate Finance Forum (Apr. 6, 1989).
150 The Effect of Mergers on Management Practices, Cost, Availability of Credit, & the Long-Term Viability of American Industry: Hearing Before the S. Subcomm. on Sec. of the Comm. On Banking, Hous. & Urban Affairs, 99th Cong. 26 (1985) (statement of Martin Lipton).
151 Memo: The Poison Pill on the First Anniversary of Household (Nov. 19, 1986), at 1.
152 Memo: Basic Concept of Poison Pill Sustained in Second CTS Case (Nov. 6, 1986).
153 Dynamics Corp. of Am, 805 F.2d at 708, 716.
154 Memo: Poison Pill Again Upheld (Nov. 11, 1986), at 1.
155 Memo: The Poison Pill on the First Anniversary of Household (Nov. 19, 1986), at 1.
156 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance in the Age of Finance Corporatism, 136 U. Penn. L. Rev. 1, 5-6 (1987).
157 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance: Major Issues for the 1990s, Address to the Third Annual Corporate Finance Forum, at 4 (Apr. 6, 1989).
158 Martin Lipton, Directors’ Responsibilities with Respect to Takeovers (1987), at 30.
159 Lipton, 136 U. Pa. L. Rev. at 37.
160 Lipton, 136 U. Pa. L. Rev. at 8-9.
161 Memo: The Investment Manager Attack on Shareholder Rights Plans (Nov. 4, 1986), at 1.
162 Memo: The Takeover Frenzy (Mar. 31, 1988), at 5.
163 Memo: Is This The End of Takeovers (Oct. 28, 1988), at 1.
164 Memo: Takeovers (Nov. 4, 1989).
165 SEC Major Issues Conference, June 28-29, 1984 (Digest of Lipton’s panel remarks).
166 Memo: Institutional Shareholder Resolutions Seeking Referendum on Share Purchase Rights Plans (Dec. 18, 1986) (quoting Warren E. Buffett, How to Tame the Casino Society, Wash. Post, Dec. 4, 1986); see also Memo: The Proxmire Takeover Bill (June 8, 1987).
167 Memo: The Attack on the Poison Pill (Nov. 24, 1986).
168 Martin Lipton, Takeover Abuses Mortgage the Future, Wall St. J., Apr. 5, 1985.
169 Tender Offer Reform Act of 1987: Hearing on H.R.1601 Before the H. Subcomm. on Telecomm. & Fin. of the H. Comm. on Energy & Commerce, 100th Cong. 44-45 (1987) (statement of Martin Lipton).
170 Martin Lipton Corporate Governance: Major Issues for the 1990s, Address to the Third Annual Corporate Finance Forum, at 9 (Apr. 6, 1989).
171 Martin Lipton, Mileposts on the Takeover Trail – From Chicago to Delaware, at 9-10 (1989).
172 Memo: Is This the End of Takeovers (Oct. 28, 1988).
173 Memo: The Investment Manager Attack on Shareholder Rights Plans (Nov. 4, 1986).
174 Memo: The Poison Pill on the First Anniversary of Household (Nov. 19, 1986).
175 Memo: The Investment Manager Attack on Shareholder Rights Plans (Nov. 4, 1986).
176 Memo: The Investment Manager Attack on Shareholder Rights Plans (Nov. 4, 1986).
177 Memo: Shareholder Referendum on Rights Plans (Nov. 13, 1986).
178 Memo: Shareholder Referendum on Rights Plans (Nov. 13, 1986).
179 Memo: Shareholder Referendum on Rights Plans (Nov. 13, 1986).
180 Memo: Shareholder Referendum on Rights Plans (Nov. 13, 1986).
181 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance in the Age of Finance Corporatism, 136 U. Penn. L. Rev. at 33 (Nov. 1987).
182 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance: Major Issues for the 1990s, Address to the Third Annual Corporate Finance Forum, at 5-6 (Apr. 6, 1989).
183 Martin Lipton, A Sensible Deterrent to Takeover Mania, N.Y. Times, Dec. 14, 1986.
184 Memo: Poison Pills: The CREF Shareholder Resolution is Defeated (Apr. 15, 1987).
185 Memo: Pill 31- Institutions 0: CALPERS and CREF Shut Out (May 26, 1987).
186 Memo: Pension Funds return with Anti-Pill Proxy Resolutions (Nov. 20, 1987).
187 Memo: The Takeover Frenzy (Mar. 31, 1988), at 4.
188 Memo: Anti-Poison Pill Resolutions Fail (May 13, 1988).
189 Memo: Anti-Poison Pill Resolutions Fail (May 13, 1988).
190 Memo: Pill Proxy Resolutions Defeated (June 10, 1988) (attaching Georgeson & Company, Inc.: Increased Vote for Poison Pill Rescission Proposals in 1988 Reflects Selective Targeting by Proponents; Vote Declines for Repeat Proposals (June 10, 1988)).
191 Memo: Pill Proxy Resolutions Defeated (June 10, 1988).
192 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987).
193 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plans: An Update and a New Plan (July 24, 1987).
194 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 2.
195 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance in the Age of Finance Corporatism, 136 U. Penn. L. Rev. at 70 (Nov. 1987).
196 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987).
197 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 3.
198 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 3.
199 See Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 4.
200 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 5.
201 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 4-5.
202 See Beneficial Ownership, Takeover and Acquisitions by Foreign and Domestic Persons: Public Investigation Hearing Before Sec. & Exch. Comm’n, 149-298, 161 (1974) (statement of Martin Lipton); Takeover Tactics and Public Policy: Hearing on H.R. 2371, H.R. 5250, H.R. 5693, H.R. 5694, H.R. 5695 and H.R. 5696: Hearings Before the H. Subcomm. on Telecomm., Consumer Prot. & Fin. of the H. Comm. on Energy & Com., 98th Cong. 98-142, 157 (1984) (statement of Martin Lipton); Impact of Corporate Takeovers: Hearings Before the H. Subcomm. on Sec. of the H. Comm. on Banking, Hous., & Urb. Affs., 98th Cong. 99-187, 10-12, 25, 142 (1985) (statement of Martin Lipton).
203 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance in the Age of Finance Corporatism, 136 U. Penn. L. Rev. at 71 (Nov. 1987).
204 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 6.
205 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 7.
206 Memo: A Second Generation Share Purchase Rights Plan (July 14, 1987), at 6.
207 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plans: An Update and a New Plan (July 24, 1987), at D-4.
208 Memo: Share Purchase Rights Plans: An Update and a New Plan (July 24, 1987), at 20.
209 Martin Lipton, Corporate Governance in the Age of Finance Corporatism, 136 U. Penn. L. Rev. at 72 (Nov. 1987).
210 Memo: The Creeping Tender Offer Is Still Alive (Nov. 4, 1987).
211 Memo: The Takeover Frenzy (Mar. 31, 1988), at 3-4.
212For more information about the litigation of Interco and other poison pill cases in Delaware after Moran, and the remembrances of key participants in those cases, see the narrative video on the cases, recorded interviews of participants, and opinions, briefs, and other materials from the cases, at Interco & Moran Videos, Penn Law, The Delaware Corporation Law Resource Center.
213Interco Inc., 551 A.2d 787 (Del. Ch. 1988).
214Memo: Is this the End of Takeovers? (Oct. 28, 1998).
215Interco, 551 A.2d at 790.
216Interco, 551 A.2d at 795.
217Interco, 551 A.2d at 796.
218Interco, 551 A.2d at 799-800.
219 Grand Metro. Pub. Ltd. v. Pillsbury Co., 558 A.2d 1049 (Del. Ch. 1988).
220 Memo: The Interco Case (Nov. 3, 1988). Chancellor Allen’s opinion itself suggests that the Chancellor viewed the objective evidence as indicating that the restructuring offered less value at more risk than the bid by the Rales, but that the stockholders, and not the court, should decide that issue for themselves as the ones bearing the primary risk of that decision.
[R]ecognizing the relative closeness of the values and the impossibility of knowing what the stub share will trade at, the board, having arranged a value maximizing restructuring, elected to preclude shareholder choice. It did so not to buy time in order to negotiate or arrange possible alternatives, but asserting in effect a right and duty to save shareholders from the consequences of the choice they might make, if permitted to choose.
Without wishing to cast any shadow upon the subjective motivation of the individual defendants . . . . I conclude that reasonable minds not affected by an inherent, entrenched interest in the matter, could not reasonably differ with respect to the conclusion that the CCA $74 cash offer did not represent a threat to shareholder interests sufficient in the circumstances to justify, in effect, foreclosing shareholders from electing to accept that offer. Interco, 551 A.2d at 799-800.
221 Memo: You Can’t Just Say No in Delaware No More (Dec. 17, 1988).
222 Leo E. Strine, Jr., The Story of Blasius Industries v. Atlas Corp.: Keeping the Electoral Path Clear in J. M. Ramseyer, Corporate Law Stories, 275 (2009).
223 William Meyers, Showdown in Delaware: The Battle to Shape Takeover Law, Institutional Inv., Feb. 1989, at 64, 75.
224 Memo:  Share Price Protection Repurchase Rights (Dec. 1, 1988). See also Memo:  Takeover Response Checklist (Nov. 23, 1988) (advocating adoption of updated firm pill and Share Price Protection Rights Plan). 
225 Memo: Progenitor’s Retrospective: The Poison Pill at Five (Jan. 10, 1989).
226 For more information about the litigation of the Time/Warner and QVC cases, and the remembrances of key participants in those cases, see the narrative video on the cases, recorded interviews of participants, and opinions, briefs, and other materials from the cases, at Time Warner and QVC Videos, Penn Law, The Delaware Corporation Law Center.
227 William Meyers, Showdown in Delaware: The Battle to Shape Takeover Law, Institutional Inv., Feb. 1989, at 64.
228 In re Time Inc. S’holder. Litig., 1989 WL 79880 (Del. Ch. July 14, 1989).
229 In re Time-Warner, 1989 WL 79880, at *13
230 In re Time-Warner, 1989 WL 79880, at *19.
231 In re Time-Warner, 1989 WL 79880, at *30.
232 In re Time-Warner, 1989 WL 79880, at *30 n.22.
233 Paramount Commc’ns, Inc. v. Time, Inc., 571 A.2d 1140 (Del. 1990).
234 Paramount, 571 A.2d at 1150.
235 Paramount, 571 A.2d at 1150.
236 Paramount, 571 A.2d at 1152-53. This characterization of Interco, as involving the courts in picking which bid was best, was objectively inaccurate. Chancellor Allen’s decision was that the stockholders, not the board, much less the court, should decide if a non-coercive bid should be accepted, once the target board had the time to tell its story, negotiate a higher price, or develop a higher valued alternative. Pillsbury took the same position.
237 Paramount, 571 A.2d at 1153.
238 Paramount, 571 A.2d at 1154.
239 Paramount, 571 A.2d at 1154.
240 Memo: Delaware Says Yes to Just Say No (Feb. 27, 1990).
241 Paramount Commc’ns, Inc. v. QVC Network, Inc., 637 A.2d 34 (Del. 1994).
242 Paramount, 637 A.2d 34.
243 Paramount, 637 A.2d at 46-47.
244 Paramount, 637 A.2d at 43.
245 Paramount, 637 A.2d at 44-46
246 Memo: Ten Questions Raised By Paramount (Feb. 7, 1994).
247 Memo: Ten Questions Raised By Paramount (Feb. 7, 1994).